26.12.2014 Views

1qGLG9p

1qGLG9p

1qGLG9p

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

72 Deleveraging, What Deleveraging<br />

which typically provides an incentive for explicit defaults. A more likely scenario<br />

for China is a combination of inflation and currency depreciation that indirectly<br />

shifts the burden of the adjustment to foreigners.<br />

In order to contain systemic risk, the Chinese government may choose to<br />

bail out some major players (either financial or non-financial) if high debt and<br />

slowing nominal growth result in some over-leveraged large entities getting in<br />

trouble. However, even if such bailouts stemmed from systemic risk, it would not<br />

be a free ride. Indeed, a combination of public bailouts and the likely burning<br />

of private shareholders would correspond to a diminished propensity to lend in<br />

the private sector and an increased perception of risk that would compound the<br />

slowdown in activity. The consequent deleveraging would be accentuated should<br />

there be, as looks likely, a sequence of relatively ‘small’ defaults by individual<br />

private entities, which the government calculates would not threaten financial<br />

stability. Although not systemic, these defaults could still affect confidence and<br />

thus activity levels.<br />

If rapid leveraging up was indeed the reason why China kept growing at a<br />

slowing, but above potential, rate since 2008, a phase of deleveraging through<br />

slower credit formation would imply a significant slowdown, with growth<br />

possibly falling below potential. Even a Chinese ‘Type 2’ crisis that avoided<br />

severe financial disruption but generated a significant growth slowdown would<br />

still have a global impact. The difference with the post-2008 crisis would be<br />

in the transmission channel: while the financial spillovers were the main<br />

transmission channel to the rest of the world in the advanced-economy crisis,<br />

the international transmission of deleveraging in China would primarily operate<br />

through lower demand for global exports. Given the prominence of China as a<br />

source of export demand in recent years, this would have a material impact on<br />

global growth performance. Furthermore, the combination of a trade slowdown<br />

and a renminbi depreciation could also generate international political economy<br />

tensions by triggering renewed debate about ‘currency wars’.<br />

It is also possible to envisage more adverse scenarios in which the Chinese<br />

authorities decide to fight the ongoing structural slowdown by maintaining the<br />

pace of leveraging up of the economy of recent years. Such a choice would increase<br />

the likelihood of a postponed, but abrupt ‘Type 3’ crisis down the road, as after<br />

another few years of rapid leveraging up even China would be unlikely to have<br />

the resources to achieve a gradual deleveraging process. Chinese policymakers are<br />

likely to remain for some time between the ‘rock’ of slowing nominal growth and<br />

the ‘hard place’ of high and rising leverage.<br />

The ‘fragile eight’<br />

Recent market concerns have focused on the so-called ‘fragile eight’ (Argentina,<br />

Brazil, Chile, India, Indonesia, Russia, South Africa and Turkey) for which various<br />

types of risk indicators have shown significant movement since 2010, even if<br />

the individual circumstances of these countries are quite diverse. Accordingly,<br />

we also examine the behaviour of two subgroups of emerging economies (EM1<br />

and EM2), where EM1 consists of the ‘fragile eight’ and EM2 consists of a second

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!