26.12.2014 Views

1qGLG9p

1qGLG9p

1qGLG9p

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

42 Deleveraging, What Deleveraging<br />

Figure 4.5<br />

Household debt-carrying costs (% of disposable income)<br />

19<br />

14<br />

18<br />

13<br />

17<br />

12<br />

16<br />

15<br />

Financial obligation ratio<br />

Debt service ratio (rhs)<br />

11<br />

14<br />

10<br />

13<br />

9<br />

01 02 03 04 05 06 07 08 09 10 11 12 13<br />

Source: Authors’ calculations based on Federal Reserve data.<br />

Unlike households and financials, the US non-financial corporate sector has<br />

already re-levered, as these firms have taken advantage of the long period of low<br />

interest rates to issue bonds and take on new, orrefinance existing, obligations.<br />

Indeed, loan and short-term market obligations are roughly at their level of the<br />

early 1990s. This lending has mostly been about finance, not real activity. Firms<br />

have built up cash buffers, increased dividends, and bought back stock. Spending<br />

on fixed investment has actually been quite subdued. For now, net interest<br />

payments remain low in light of the Federal Reserve’s policy accommodation.<br />

As opposed to that of households, the debt of non-financial firms tends to<br />

have a longer maturity, lengthening the runway before interest costs take off<br />

substantially when the Fed begins to tighten.<br />

What raises worries about over-borrowing in the private sector is the other side<br />

of the transactions –over-lending by investors. For six years, the Federal Reserve<br />

has kept the short-term interest rate low and purchased long-duration Treasury<br />

securities and convex mortgage-backed securities. This is a direct encouragement<br />

to investors to stretch for yield in alternative, often less familiar, markets. In<br />

effect, the Fed has been ‘recruiting’ investors to purchase risky assets (Stein,<br />

2012). The problem is that not all investors may appreciate the extent of the<br />

risk they acquire in the bargain. This suggests that focusing solely on economywide<br />

aggregate quantities is not sufficient to appreciate potential system risks<br />

associated with the re-leveraging of the US economy. Monitoring also has to<br />

encompass asset prices, risk spreads and activity in specific market niches.<br />

Indeed, across the world there is considerable heterogeneity in the sensitivity<br />

of aggregate demand to housing. There are several reasons to suspect that it is on<br />

the high side in the US: housing tends to make up a higher share of household<br />

wealth; home ownership is higher than in most other countries and reaches<br />

further down the income distribution; and non-recourse, long-term, fixed-rate<br />

mortgages provide an effective mechanism to tap equity. But perhaps most<br />

importantly, homes represent a key source of collateral, sometimes embedded

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!