22.05.2013 Views

bain_y_howells__monetary_economics__policy_and_its_theoretical_basis

bain_y_howells__monetary_economics__policy_and_its_theoretical_basis

bain_y_howells__monetary_economics__policy_and_its_theoretical_basis

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

a deterministic trend) <strong>and</strong> define P-Star as money per unit of real potential<br />

output. In other words, the Quantity Theory equation becomes:<br />

P* = (M/y*)V*<br />

with y* <strong>and</strong> V* representing long-run equilibrium levels of output <strong>and</strong><br />

velocity. The models are then used to indicate the existence of inflationary<br />

pressures in the economy by comparing current levels of income <strong>and</strong> velocity<br />

with their long-run equilibrium levels. If current income is above longrun<br />

equilibrium income, (y > y*), then, ceteris paribus, current income must<br />

fall in the long-run, with the existing <strong>monetary</strong> pressures in the economy<br />

being transferred to the price level. Equally, if current velocity is below <strong>its</strong><br />

long-run level, it must rise in the long-run generating increased expansionary<br />

pressure that must fall on y or P. Plainly, if y = Y*, all additional <strong>monetary</strong><br />

pressure will fall upon P. Thus, short-run movements in the price<br />

level are modelled as the product of an output gap, (Y - Y*), <strong>and</strong> a velocity<br />

gap, (V − V*). However, the P-Star approach suffers from the same problems<br />

as other cointegrating studies in that, to obtain definite answers, one<br />

must impose on the models assumptions drawn from economic theory,<br />

notably here the assumption of a long-run equilibrium velocity of money.<br />

We are also left to explain the short-term deviations of V from V*.<br />

In general, while cointegration studies have been judged useful, they<br />

have not yet been able to establish a stable dem<strong>and</strong> for money function with<br />

a specific form <strong>and</strong> invariant coefficients for out-of-sample data. We need,<br />

therefore, to consider the principal explanations of the continuing problems<br />

with the function.<br />

Shocks to the dem<strong>and</strong> for money function<br />

TESTING THE DEMAND FOR MONEY 151<br />

...6.7<br />

Economists have proposed a number of possible causes of sudden shifts in the<br />

dem<strong>and</strong> for money function in the 1970s <strong>and</strong> 1980s. These have included:<br />

(i) financial innovations associated with institutional change in the<br />

financial sector;<br />

(ii) uncertainty about the rate of inflation as a result of the large swings<br />

in inflation rates in the 1970s <strong>and</strong> 1980s;<br />

(iii) currency substitution, especially following the movement away<br />

from fixed exchange rates in the early 1970s.<br />

Although we shall say a little about the second <strong>and</strong> third of these, we<br />

concentrate here on the impact of financial innovations since this has produced<br />

by far the greatest amount of lucubration.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!