22.05.2013 Views

bain_y_howells__monetary_economics__policy_and_its_theoretical_basis

bain_y_howells__monetary_economics__policy_and_its_theoretical_basis

bain_y_howells__monetary_economics__policy_and_its_theoretical_basis

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

THE MEANING OF MONEY 5<br />

<strong>and</strong> so we have the possibility that money might take a variety of forms.<br />

Nonetheless, for most people the word ‘currency’ indicates notes <strong>and</strong> coin<br />

or cash or what might be called ‘ready money’ in everyday use. And yet,<br />

the underlying idea remains that ‘money’ is anything that is acceptable in<br />

payment for goods <strong>and</strong> services, <strong>and</strong> payment can occur without the transfer<br />

of a physical asset. The most obvious example of this is the use of<br />

cheques or debit cards to transfer funds from one bank account to another.<br />

This leads to the notion that neither the cheque nor the debit card is money<br />

but that the bank depos<strong>its</strong> people can call upon in order to make purchases<br />

are money since the exchange is validated by the circulation of the bank<br />

depos<strong>its</strong> to which cheques <strong>and</strong> debit cards refer<br />

We begin to see the difficulty. ‘Money’, in <strong>monetary</strong> <strong>economics</strong>, does<br />

not mean income or wealth. Rather, ‘money’ is any asset acceptable in<br />

exchange for goods <strong>and</strong> services. We shall see that <strong>monetary</strong> economists<br />

have spent a great deal of time discussing <strong>and</strong> testing the ‘dem<strong>and</strong> for<br />

money’. If we define ‘money’ as a set of assets generally acceptable in<br />

exchange for goods <strong>and</strong> services, the dem<strong>and</strong> for money is only an indirect<br />

dem<strong>and</strong>. What people dem<strong>and</strong> are goods <strong>and</strong> services but they may need<br />

money in order to carry out the act of exchange.<br />

The first problem we face, then, arises because a variety of types of asset<br />

may allow exchange to take place. This is especially so at an individual<br />

level. Consider a person who has decided to give up stamp collecting but<br />

who has a philatelist friend. The ex-stamp collector agrees to exchange his<br />

stamp albums for a number of CDs. Plainly, the stamp collection has a<br />

<strong>monetary</strong> value — it could be sold to a stamp dealer <strong>and</strong> the money thus<br />

obtained could be used to buy other goods <strong>and</strong> services. However, the<br />

stamp collection is not <strong>its</strong>elf ‘money’ since for an asset to be considered as<br />

such it must be generally or widely acceptable directly in exchange for<br />

goods <strong>and</strong> services, not merely be acceptable in an occasional private transaction.<br />

That is, to be classed as ‘money’, an asset must be exchangeable for<br />

goods <strong>and</strong> services in general.<br />

Thus, ‘money’ is a sub-set of all those assets that might be acceptable in<br />

exchange. Once we acknowledge this, we introduce an element of uncertainty.<br />

To decide which assets are ‘money’ <strong>and</strong> which are not, we need to<br />

say what precisely we mean by ‘generally acceptable’. Further, the assets<br />

that are generally acceptable in exchange might vary from one country to<br />

another or from one period to another within the same country. As<br />

Goodhart (1989a) notes, money is a social phenomenon that exists in all<br />

societies but that is everywhere different.<br />

Our second problem is more important. We need to say something about

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!