13.08.2013 Views

Powering Europe - European Wind Energy Association

Powering Europe - European Wind Energy Association

Powering Europe - European Wind Energy Association

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

analysis<br />

Merit order and volume merit order<br />

effect<br />

As shown in the previous chapter, due to wind’s lower<br />

marginal costs (zero fuel costs), when there is more<br />

of it on the power system, it replaces conventional<br />

technologies and the price goes down. Consequently,<br />

some of the most expensive conventional power<br />

plants might be no longer needed to meet demand.<br />

At a fixed demand level, as long as the whole merit<br />

order curve has a positive slope, the reduced conventional<br />

supply leads to a lower average power price. As<br />

this means market prices are shifted along the meritorder<br />

of the market’s power technologies, the effect is<br />

called merit order effect (MOE).<br />

In this study, the merit order effect is determined by<br />

calculating the difference in the long-term equilibrium<br />

price level of the Reference scenario and the <strong>Wind</strong><br />

scenario.<br />

In the analysis, the merit order effect – the difference<br />

between the equilibrium price levels in the two scenarios<br />

– has been estimated at 1.08 €cent/kWh or<br />

€10.8/MWh. The Reference scenario resulted in an<br />

equilibrium price of 8.58 €cent/kWh whereas the<br />

<strong>Wind</strong> scenario indicated a price of 7.5 €cent/kWh.<br />

Assuming that the entire power demand is purchased<br />

at the marginal price, the overall volume of the MOE<br />

can be calculated for the scenarios. The “volume effect”<br />

refers to the total savings made due to wind<br />

power penetration in a particular year. The price difference<br />

of the two scenarios would represent the<br />

volume merit order effect of increased wind power<br />

capacities. It could be calculated by taking the<br />

equilibrium price difference of both scenarios, 1.08<br />

€cent/kWh, multiplied by the <strong>Wind</strong> scenario’s overall<br />

demand of 3,860 TWh.<br />

The overall volume merit order effect, comparing the<br />

<strong>Wind</strong> scenario price with the Reference scenario price<br />

would then be €41.7 billion per year 12 .<br />

148<br />

However, it would be misleading to interpret this as<br />

the overall economic benefit of increased wind power<br />

generation. When wind power reduces the average<br />

power price, it has a significant influence on the price<br />

of power for consumers. When the price is lowered,<br />

this is beneficial to all power consumers, since the<br />

reduction in price applies to all electricity traded – not<br />

only to electricity generated by wind power. However,<br />

at the same time, the power producers’ short-term income<br />

decreases at lower power prices, meaning the<br />

MOE causes a redistribution of income from the producers<br />

to the consumers of electricity. Only the longterm<br />

marginal part of the generation which is replaced<br />

by wind has a real economic benefit.<br />

However, the assumed amount of additional wind power<br />

investments has an economic cost, usually given<br />

through investment subsidies, feed-in tariffs or other<br />

support. For this reason, in order to determine the actual<br />

economic benefit of increased wind power generation,<br />

the annual savings in costs deriving from the<br />

merit order effect should be related to the total annual<br />

costs in form of wind power support.<br />

There is only an overall economic benefit if the volume<br />

of the merit order effect exceeds the net support for<br />

wind power generation, paid for by the end-consumer.<br />

Ideally, subsidies to fossil fuel and nuclear power<br />

should also be taken into account to determine the<br />

economic benefits, but this is beyond the scope of<br />

this analysis.<br />

tablE 3: oVERViEw on MoDEllinG REsUlts: MERit oRDER<br />

anD VolUME MERit oRDER EffECt.<br />

wind<br />

generation<br />

volume<br />

Merit<br />

order<br />

effect<br />

Volume<br />

order<br />

effect<br />

Merit order<br />

effect per<br />

wind Mwh<br />

Year TWh/a €/MWh billion €/a €/MWh<br />

2020 648 10.8 41.7 64.4*<br />

*This figure indicates the merit order effect for 1 MWh of wind power. It is calculated<br />

by dividing the volume order effect by the total wind generation volume. It should be<br />

compared to the support level given to wind power generation per MWh, in order to<br />

estimate the economic benefits of wind power.<br />

12 In the project’s first phase, the conducted literature survey indicated some volume order effects, only for single countries, e.g.<br />

Germany. There, a volume order effect of €1.3 - 5 billion per annum has been shown. In comparison, this model analysis would<br />

result at a volume order effect of €6.7 billion per annum for Germany, if looking at the country specific results only.<br />

<strong>Powering</strong> <strong>Europe</strong>: wind energy and the electricity grid

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!