28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

230 Equilibrium exchange rates<br />

A number of researchers (see,for example,Brigden et al. 1997) have used this<br />

expression to calculate a measure of the (short- to medium-run) equilibrium<br />

exchange rate. For example,absent a risk premium,if the interest rate in the<br />

home country is x% above that in its trading partner its currency will be expected<br />

to depreciate by x% over the maturity of the bonds used to define i <strong>and</strong> i ∗ . On the<br />

basis of this relationship it should therefore be possible to say where an exchange<br />

rate will be in period k (the maturity period). However,as we noted in Chapter 1<br />

(<strong>and</strong> as is discussed again in Chapter 15) there is little empirical support for this<br />

relationship on its own <strong>and</strong> therefore drawing inferences purely on the basis of<br />

(9.8) is hazardous.<br />

A related approach to explaining the persistence in real exchange rates,<strong>and</strong><br />

also in obtaining well-defined measures of the equilibrium exchange rate,involves<br />

combining an interest differential with PPP. This approach has been popularised by<br />

Johansen <strong>and</strong> Juselius (1990),Juselius (1995),MacDonald <strong>and</strong> Marsh (1997,1999)<br />

<strong>and</strong> Juselius <strong>and</strong> MacDonald (2004,2007). We refer to this approach as a capital<br />

enhanced equilibrium exchange rate,or CHEER. The approach captures the basic<br />

Casselian view of PPP,discussed in Chapter 6,that an exchange rate may be away<br />

from its PPP determined rate because of non-zero interest differentials. In terms<br />

of expression (9.1),therefore,the approach focuses on the interaction between the<br />

real exchange rate <strong>and</strong> the capital account items; it ignores the relative output<br />

terms <strong>and</strong> net foreign assets (<strong>and</strong> indeed any other ‘real’ determinants). Unlike<br />

the pure form of Casselian PPP,in which non-zero interest differentials only have<br />

a transitory impact on the real exchange rate,here the interest rates can have a<br />

medium-run,or business cycle,effect. The essential proposition of this approach is<br />

that the long-term persistence in the real exchange rate is mirrored in the interest<br />

differential. We consider the CHEERs approach first from a statistical perspective<br />

<strong>and</strong> then from an economic perspective.<br />

Since interest differentials are usually empirically found to be I (1) processes<br />

(see,for example,Juselius <strong>and</strong> MacDonald 2004,2007) some combination of an<br />

appropriate interest differential <strong>and</strong> the real exchange rate may cointegrate down<br />

to a stationary process. More specifically,if the expected exchange rate in (9.8) is<br />

used to determine the relative prices,as in an absolute PPP condition,we may use<br />

(9.8) to derive the following relationship:<br />

(i t − i ∗ t ) = ω 2(p t − p ∗ t ) − s t,(9.9)<br />

or,less restrictively,as:<br />

[ω 1 (i t − i ∗ t ) − ω 2(p t − p ∗ t ) + s t]∼I (0). (9.10)<br />

The reason why an appropriate interest differential <strong>and</strong> real exchange rate may<br />

cointegrate is as follows. For a period such as the recent float we know that there<br />

have been large current account imbalances (this is especially clear when the US<br />

dollar is the bilateral numeraire) <strong>and</strong> these have been driven in large measure by<br />

national savings imbalances,such as fiscal imbalances. The fact that real exchange

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!