28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

354 Market microstructure approach<br />

to pay a liquidity premium for the service of predictable immediacy. However,in<br />

this model traders have inside,or asymmetric,information about,say,a potential<br />

arbitrage opportunity,<strong>and</strong> can engage in favourable speculation against the market<br />

maker. The adverse selection arises because in a market with competing market<br />

makers,the one who interacts with the trader with inside information is the loser.<br />

In a decentralised market with no consensus on price,setting a single price is a<br />

dangerous strategy for a trader because he is vulnerable to the inside arbitrage<br />

opportunity. By setting a bid–ask spread the market maker allows a tolerance for<br />

error <strong>and</strong> it is easier to get spreads to overlap (which would represent a consensus)<br />

than to get a scalar price to overlap. The spread therefore gives the market maker<br />

some degree of protection from adverse selection arbitrage. Bagehot (1971) argued<br />

that the losses incurred by the market maker from the better-informed traders<br />

must be compensated by the less well-informed traders,<strong>and</strong> this idea has been<br />

formalised in the asymmetric information models of,for example,Admati <strong>and</strong><br />

Pfleider (1988) <strong>and</strong> Subrahmanyam (1991) <strong>and</strong> we consider these models <strong>and</strong> their<br />

predictions here.<br />

In the model of Admati <strong>and</strong> Pfleider (1988),there are three types of agents:<br />

informed traders,who only trade on terms advantageous to them; discretionary<br />

liquidity traders who must trade over the trading day,but have some discretion<br />

at what point in the day to trade; non-discretionary liquidity traders who must<br />

trade at a given time during the day,irrespective of cost. In high volume periods<br />

both informed <strong>and</strong> discretionary traders are attracted to trade. The informed are<br />

attracted because they are better able to disguise their activity due to the behaviour<br />

of the uninformed traders. The discretionary liquidity traders are also attracted<br />

at this point because the increased activity amongst the informed traders implies<br />

increased competition amongst them <strong>and</strong> the cost of trading is lowered for the<br />

uninformed. Using this model they are able to explain some of the stylised facts of<br />

the NYSE stock market: the high volume exhibited at the open <strong>and</strong> close of trade is<br />

explained by the earlier kind of equilibrium mechanism while the concurrent high<br />

variance at open <strong>and</strong> close follows on from the increased activity of the informed<br />

traders who exploit previously private information.<br />

Subrahmanyam (1991) builds on the model of Admati <strong>and</strong> Pfleider (1988) to<br />

show that their key result,that increased activity by the informed trader lowers<br />

the costs to the uninformed who pay the price of the informed,depends on the<br />

assumption that the informed traders are risk neutral. If,in contrast,the informed<br />

traders are risk averse then Subrahmanyam shows that increased activity by them<br />

actually leads to an increase in the trading costs of liquidity traders.<br />

A further way in which this has been modelled is in terms of inventory considerations.<br />

For example,in the so-called r<strong>and</strong>om walk inventory model (starting with<br />

Barnea <strong>and</strong> Logue 1975) the market maker has a desired inventory level (equal<br />

to zero) <strong>and</strong> a constant spread is shifted up <strong>and</strong> down on a price scale to ensure<br />

that the expected change in inventory is always zero; hence the level of inventory<br />

follows a r<strong>and</strong>om walk. However,this has the unpleasant consequence that the<br />

market maker inevitably becomes bankrupt. This follows because market makers<br />

face finite capitalisation levels which,in turn,force upper <strong>and</strong> lower bounds on

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!