28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

384 Spot <strong>and</strong> forward exchange rates<br />

of the portfolio-balance model is that these terms are restricted <strong>and</strong> in the<br />

following way:<br />

<strong>and</strong><br />

α t =−0.5 · Var t (s t+1 ),<br />

δ t = (1 − φ) · Var t (s t+1 ),<br />

γ t = φVar t (s t+1 ).<br />

The majority of the papers in the mean-variance portfolio-balance approach<br />

involve estimating variants of equation (15.45) <strong>and</strong> testing the restrictions that<br />

(15.46) imposes on (15.45). It is worth noting that one of the big empirical advantages<br />

of this approach is that it only requires information on the value of total bonds<br />

held in the world denominated in each country,<strong>and</strong> the share of wealth in each<br />

country,rather than the value of bonds denominated in each country <strong>and</strong> held in<br />

each country (the latter data are much less readily available than the former).<br />

Frankel (1982a,b,1983),Lewis (1988) <strong>and</strong> Rogoff (1984) present estimates of<br />

variants of (15.38) (i.e the st<strong>and</strong>ard unconstrained portfolio-balance equation) for<br />

a variety of currencies <strong>and</strong> time periods <strong>and</strong> essentially find no evidence of a<br />

statistically significant link between excess returns <strong>and</strong> bond holdings.<br />

Engel <strong>and</strong> Rodriguez (1989) estimate a version of (15.45) for the dem<strong>and</strong> for<br />

government bonds for six countries. Since they assume all investors evaluate returns<br />

in the same terms,the equation they estimate is equivalent to (15.42) <strong>and</strong> the<br />

variance is modelled using an ARCH model <strong>and</strong> also models which relate the<br />

variance to economic data. The estimates of φ turn out to be either insignificantly<br />

different from zero or negative <strong>and</strong> therefore do not offer support to the meanvariance<br />

approach. Giovannini <strong>and</strong> Jorion also offer GARCH-based estimates<br />

of (15.42) which are also unsupportive of the mean-variance approach since the<br />

estimates of the coefficient of risk aversion are insignificant. Other unsupportive<br />

estimates of this approach have been produced by Lyons (1988),Thomas <strong>and</strong><br />

Wickens (1993),Engel <strong>and</strong> Rodriguez (1993) <strong>and</strong> Tesar <strong>and</strong> Werner (1994).<br />

By incorporating a home country bias effect,as in equation (15.45),<strong>and</strong> using a<br />

GARCH process to model volatility,Engel (1994) produces a reasonably plausible<br />

estimate of the coefficient of risk aversion which is marginally significant; however,<br />

the risk premiums implied by estimates of equation (15.45) ‘are more than an order<br />

of magnitude greater than those from the estimated CAPM’ (Engel 1996). Black<br />

<strong>and</strong> Salemi (1988) do not assume the first-order maximisation condition from the<br />

consumers’ maximisation problem holds exactly <strong>and</strong> add an error term to (15.45)<br />

<strong>and</strong> this produces a statistically significant value of φ of 4.08,but they do not<br />

provide estimates of the size of the implied risk premiums <strong>and</strong> how they relate to<br />

estimates derived from equation (15.45). Lewis,however,reports estimates of a<br />

version of the model which is subject to an error term,but in contrast to Black <strong>and</strong><br />

Salemi she finds no evidence in support of the model.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!