28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Speculative attack models <strong>and</strong> contagion 331<br />

The estimated one step ahead probabilities increase quite sharply before each of<br />

these devaluations,<strong>and</strong> decline sharply thereafter. Ninety-five per cent confidence<br />

intervals are also constructed for the conditional expected exchange rates (forecasts)<br />

<strong>and</strong> these show that for the 1976:Q3 devaluation the conditional expected<br />

exchange rate falls within the confidence interval,but the 1981 devaluation<br />

does not.<br />

Cumby <strong>and</strong> Wijnbergen (1989) use a similar analysis <strong>and</strong> monthly data to analyse<br />

the Argentine crawling peg,1979–80. Consistent with the basic model,they find<br />

that a sharp increase in growth of domestic credit is the main factor triggering an<br />

attack on the currency.<br />

13.2.2 Empirical evidence on self-fulfilling crises <strong>and</strong><br />

escape clause models<br />

A number of papers have used Markov–Switching-regime models in an attempt to<br />

capture regime changes which are unrelated to fundamentals. For example,Jeanne<br />

<strong>and</strong> Masson (2000) have proposed interpreting the regime shifts identified by<br />

such models as jumps between multiple equilibria because the Markov–Switchingregime<br />

model can be interpreted as a linear reduced form of a structural escape<br />

clause model with sunspots. In particular,Jeanne <strong>and</strong> Masson (2000) estimate a<br />

two-state Markov–Switching model for the French franc–German mark exchange<br />

rate over the period 1979–86. They follow the second generation/escape clause<br />

literature <strong>and</strong> include a broader range of fundamentals than in the first generation<br />

models. In particular,the probability of devaluation was specified as:<br />

π t = γ st + β u u t + β b tbal t + β r rer t + v t ,(13.42)<br />

where u represents the unemployment rate,tbal is the trade balance as a ratio<br />

of GDP,rer is percentage deviation of the real effective exchange rate from its<br />

1990 level <strong>and</strong> the dependent variable is the 1 month interest differential between<br />

euro-franc <strong>and</strong> euro-DM instruments,after correction for the expected movement<br />

towards the centre of the b<strong>and</strong> using the risk-adjusted method of Svensson (1993)<br />

(see Chapter 12). The error term is assumed to be normally distributed with variance<br />

σ 2 v . The constant term depends on two potential states (i.e. s t = 1or2)<strong>and</strong><br />

is the term which captures the potential multiple equilibria in this class of model.<br />

Assuming this term is constant,estimates of the purely fundamental-based model<br />

are recovered using OLS. Jeanne <strong>and</strong> Masson find that the coefficient estimates<br />

recovered are often wrongly signed <strong>and</strong> the fitted value from this expression does<br />

not do a good job of tracking the actual probability of devaluation,particularly<br />

in periods associated with speculation. However,when the two-state model is<br />

estimated,the fit of the model improves dramatically,all of the coefficients are<br />

correctly signed <strong>and</strong> the actual <strong>and</strong> fitted probabilities track each other closely,<br />

particularly around the periods of speculative pressure. Jeanne <strong>and</strong> Masson infer<br />

from this that the Markov–Switching model provides a better fit for the probability

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!