28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

372 Spot <strong>and</strong> forward exchange rates<br />

There are a very large number of estimates of α 1 for different currencies <strong>and</strong> time<br />

periods (see, inter alia,MacDonald <strong>and</strong> Taylor 1989) <strong>and</strong> these studies produce a<br />

preponderance of estimates of α 1 which are closer to −1 than +1. For example,<br />

Froot <strong>and</strong> Thaler (1990) demonstrate that averaging α 1 over 75 published produces<br />

a value of −0.88. We present an example of an estimated version of expression<br />

(15.4) here,from Fama (1984),for the Swiss franc–US dollar:<br />

s t+k = 0.81<br />

(0.42) − 1.15<br />

(0.50) (f t − s t ) + u t . (15.5)<br />

How may this stylised result be explained? There are essentially two potential<br />

explanations: it is either caused by some form of expectational failure,which can<br />

range from simple irrationality through to a ‘peso’ effect,or learning,or simply<br />

a time-varying risk premium. These alternative explanations may be illustrated<br />

using the so-called Fama (1984) decomposition,but before considering this we<br />

outline some other ways of testing the informational efficiency of the forward<br />

exchange rate.<br />

Forward market efficiency has also been tested using the rational forecast error<br />

(alternatively labelled in the literature,later,as the excess return premium or the<br />

rational risk premium – s t+1 −f t ). By regressing this error onto lagged information<br />

we may obtain alternative,<strong>and</strong> potentially stronger,tests of efficiency. A so-called<br />

weak-form test of efficiency 1 would simply involve regressing the current forecast<br />

error onto past forecast errors:<br />

s t+1 − f t = δ 0 +<br />

p∑<br />

λ i (s t−i − f t−i−1 ) + ω t ,(15.6)<br />

i=0<br />

where the null hypothesis would be δ 0 = 0 <strong>and</strong> ∑ p<br />

i=0 λ i= 0. A stronger test would<br />

involve running the following regression:<br />

s t+1 − f t = δ 0 +<br />

p∑<br />

λ i X t−i + ω t ,(15.7)<br />

i=1<br />

where X is an n × 1 vector containing any publicly available information,such<br />

as money supplies,forecast errors from other foreign exchange markets,<strong>and</strong> so<br />

on. The joint null hypothesis in this case would be δ 0 = 0 <strong>and</strong> ∑ p<br />

i=1 λ i = 0<br />

<strong>and</strong> this would be interpreted as a semi-strong-form test of efficiency. Using the<br />

terminology of Fama (1970) a strong-form test of efficiency would involve including<br />

non-publicly available,or inside,information in the information set,X t (the issue<br />

of inside information is not addressed further in this chapter but is considered in<br />

Chapter 14).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!