28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Equilibrium exchange rates 231<br />

rates have been so persistent,<strong>and</strong> therefore any adjustment of the current account<br />

to relative prices is painfully slow (see Juselius <strong>and</strong> MacDonald 2004,2007),means<br />

that the current account imbalances have to be financed through the capital<br />

account of the balance of payments. This,in turn,means that the persistence<br />

observed in real exchange rates should get transferred through into persistence<br />

in a nominal interest differential (in particular,an interest differential with a similar<br />

maturity to the evident persistence in real exchange rates). The CHEERs<br />

approach,therefore,involves exploiting the following vector:<br />

x t ′ =[s t , p t , pt ∗ , i t, it ∗ ]. (9.11)<br />

In MacDonald <strong>and</strong> Marsh (1999) equation (9.11) is estimated using the methods of<br />

Johansen for the US dollar bilateral rates of the DM,pound sterling <strong>and</strong> Japanese<br />

yen over the period January 1974 through to December 1992. For each country<br />

evidence of two significant cointegrating vectors is found <strong>and</strong> in each case the first<br />

vector can be identified to have a similar form to that of the German mark–US<br />

dollar exchange rate:<br />

s t = p t − p ∗ t − 7.33(i t − i ∗ t ),(9.12)<br />

which indicates that the coefficient on relative prices can be constrained to have a<br />

coefficient of plus <strong>and</strong> minus unity <strong>and</strong> the coefficient on the interest differential has<br />

a traditional capital flow interpretation. Potentially then this relationship could be<br />

used as a measure of the equilibrium exchange rate. However,one problem with<br />

this initial approach is that the second significant cointegrating vector could not<br />

be identified. This issue was solved in MacDonald <strong>and</strong> Marsh (2004) where it was<br />

argued that to be able to identify both vectors in a system like (9.11) the close linkages<br />

in currency markets should be recognised in any econometric exercise by modelling<br />

currencies <strong>and</strong> their determinants jointly. Taking the tripolar relationship between<br />

Germany,the US <strong>and</strong> Japan as an example,this means modelling the following<br />

vector:<br />

x ′ t = [ s ger<br />

t<br />

, s jap<br />

t<br />

, p ger<br />

t<br />

, p jap<br />

t , p us<br />

t , i ger<br />

t<br />

, i jap<br />

t<br />

, i us ]<br />

. (9.13)<br />

MacDonald <strong>and</strong> Marsh (2004) demonstrate that two significant cointegrating vectors<br />

exist amongst the variables in (9.11) <strong>and</strong> by testing hypotheses on this vector<br />

they demonstrate how it may be partitioned into two stationary relationships for<br />

Germany <strong>and</strong> Japan of the form:<br />

t<br />

β ger x =[ω 1 (i ger − i us ) − ω 2 (p ger − p us ) + s ger ],<br />

β jap x =[ω 3 (i jap − i us ) − ω 4 (p jap − p us ) + s jap ],<br />

(9.14)<br />

where ω 2 <strong>and</strong> ω 4 could be restricted to unity in both equations <strong>and</strong> ω 1 <strong>and</strong><br />

ω 3 were estimated significantly positive (i.e. significantly negative in equation<br />

form). These relationships indicate that although no direct spillovers appear in the

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!