28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

The new open economy macroeconomics part 2 285<br />

premium is too small to match the data <strong>and</strong>,as a result,the exchange rate changes<br />

they produce are also too small. Duarte <strong>and</strong> Stockman suggest that further modifications<br />

to the model,such as modelling the equity-premium <strong>and</strong> the introduction<br />

of irrational speculation,may help to generate sufficient exchange rate variability.<br />

Monacelli (2004) takes a stochastic small open economy version of the NOEM<br />

model,in which there is an explicit role for capital accumulation (where capital is<br />

assumed to be a function of Tobin’s q) <strong>and</strong> pricing to market,in order to examine<br />

the issue of intra-regime volatility. The main novelty of this work is to introduce into<br />

this class of model an open economy variant of a Taylor style interest rate monetary<br />

rule which allows an analysis of the short-run dynamic effects of a change in the<br />

nominal exchange rate regime. Specifically,the equation for the target for the<br />

nominal interest rate is:<br />

( ) ωπ PH ,t<br />

(1 + ī t ) =<br />

Y ω y<br />

t S ω s/(1−ω s )<br />

t . (11.27)<br />

P H ,t−1<br />

From this expression the monetary authority reacts to the contemporaneous level<br />

of the nominal exchange rate (a forward-looking jump variable) <strong>and</strong> to contemporaneous<br />

inflation <strong>and</strong> output. The use of this rule allows Monacelli to consider<br />

fixed <strong>and</strong> floating exchange rate regimes in the context of the NOEM. If ω s = 0<br />

this implies a flexible rate regime whereas if ω s ∈[0,1] this allows for a range of<br />

managed to fixed exchange rates. It is then assumed that the monetary authority<br />

smooth interest rates using the following rule:<br />

(1 + i t ) = (1 + ī t ) 1−χ (1 + i t−1 ) χ ,(11.28)<br />

<strong>and</strong> by taking a log-linear approximation of these two equations it is possible to<br />

obtain:<br />

i t =¯ω π π H ,t +¯ω y y t +¯ω s s t + χi t−1 ,(11.29)<br />

where ¯ω π ≡ (1 − χ)ω π , ¯ω y = (1 − χ)ω y , ¯ω s = (1 − χ)(ω s /1 − ω s ), i t ≈<br />

log(1 + i t /1 + i).<br />

The model is then calibrated <strong>and</strong> solved numerically for the instances of complete<br />

<strong>and</strong> incomplete pass-through. In the complete pass-through case,Monacelli (2004)<br />

shows that in moving from fixed to flexible exchange rates there is a proportional<br />

rise in the volatility of the nominal exchange rate which is coupled with a rise in<br />

the real exchange rate which roughly mimics what we observe in the data. He<br />

shows that the interest rate smoothing objective is crucial in generating this result.<br />

Furthermore,the close correlation between real <strong>and</strong> nominal exchange rates in<br />

a flexible rate regime is mimicked in this model <strong>and</strong> these results are robust with<br />

respect to the sources of the underlying shocks. However,this version of the model<br />

produces a correlation between nominal depreciation <strong>and</strong> inflation which is too<br />

high relative to the actual correlation in the data. Nonetheless,it is demonstrated

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!