28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

380 Spot <strong>and</strong> forward exchange rates<br />

Hansen <strong>and</strong> Hodrick (1983) test (15.26) by assuming that the conditional<br />

covariances between returns <strong>and</strong> the marginal rate of substitution move in proportion<br />

across assets over time. With this assumption the ratios of covariances in<br />

(15.24) or β in (15.26) are constant. Their approach may be viewed as a latent<br />

variable approach because R b is unobservable <strong>and</strong> it implies a set of overidentifying<br />

restrictions. With β assumed constant,<strong>and</strong> forward forecast errors used as<br />

instruments,Hansen <strong>and</strong> Hodrick find that the overidentifying restrictions are not<br />

rejected. However,in an alternative set of tests Hodrick <strong>and</strong> Srivastava (1984) find<br />

that the overidentifying restrictions are rejected when f −s,the forward premium,<br />

is used as an instrument. There are a large number of other tests of the latent<br />

variable model <strong>and</strong> these produce mixed results (see also Hodrick <strong>and</strong> Srivastava<br />

1986; Campbell <strong>and</strong> Clarida 1987; Giovannini <strong>and</strong> Jorion 1987). However,even<br />

tests which do not reject the overidentifying restrictions are unable to provide a<br />

measure of how much of the forward premium puzzle is explained by the risk<br />

premium term. Cumby (1990) <strong>and</strong> Lewis (1991) argue that one reason for the<br />

rejections of the model could be due to the auxiliary assumption that covariances<br />

move in proportion to each other. They note that this condition only seems to hold<br />

at longer horizons <strong>and</strong> when long horizon returns are used there is less evidence<br />

of rejection; however,this failure to reject at long horizons could simply reflect the<br />

low power of the test.<br />

15.3.2.3 Hansen–Jaganathan bounds<br />

The Hansen–Jaganathan approach uses combinations of excess returns to provide<br />

a lower bound on the volatility of the inter-temporal marginal rate of substitution in<br />

consumption – the Q t term. This lower bound is seen as a useful empirical tool for<br />

comparing excess returns – here the excess return from taking a forward position –<br />

with the implications of a particular model,in this case the general equilibrium<br />

model of Lucas. The derivation of these bounds may be illustrated in the following<br />

way (see,for example,Lewis 1995). Consider again (15.27):<br />

E t {Q t+1 ex t+1 }=0,<br />

where the j superscript has been dropped.<br />

If it is assumed that Q t can be written in terms of a simple linear projection as:<br />

Q t+1 = δ 0 + δ ′ ex t+1 + e t+1 ,(15.31)<br />

where e is the error term. Using the st<strong>and</strong>ard OLS formulae the parameter vector<br />

can be written as:<br />

δ = ∑ −1<br />

[E(Q t+1 ex t+1 ) − E(Q t+1 )E(ex t+1 )],(15.32)<br />

which given (15.27) implies<br />

=− ∑ −1<br />

E(Q t+1 )E(ex t+1 ),<br />

where ∑ is the variance,or variance covariance matrix (if ex is a vector) of ex.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!