28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Notes 403<br />

2 Here the j superscript does not appear because we have imposed symmetry on the<br />

identical agents within each country.<br />

3 Where 1 + i t = (P t+1 )/(P t )(1 + r t+1 ).<br />

4 Note also that equilibrium is characterised by a situation in which the following<br />

transversality condition holds:<br />

(<br />

lim R t,t+T B t+T +1 + M )<br />

t+T<br />

= 0.<br />

T →∞ P t+T<br />

5 That is,from (10.11) we have 1 = β(1+r) <strong>and</strong> therefore there is no consumption tilting<br />

in steady state.<br />

6 S ′ ,the steady-state change in the exchange rate,appears here as the representation of<br />

the expected exchange rate change in period t + 1,given the assumption that the model<br />

gets back to steady state in one period.<br />

7 This equation is derived by using equations (10.31),(10.39),(10.35) <strong>and</strong> (10.36) with<br />

home <strong>and</strong> foreign government spending subtracted <strong>and</strong> using (10.49).<br />

8 Hau (2000) introduces non-traded goods into the two-country redux model,considered<br />

in the last section. He demonstrates that this introduction increases the size of the initial<br />

exchange rate movement in response to a monetary shock (because non-traded prices<br />

are tied down by the sticky nominal wage assumption,a larger exchange rate movement<br />

is required to get a given change in the aggregate price level).<br />

9 Therefore,we do not need to consider the production of the traded good.<br />

11 The new open economymacroeconomic model: pricing<br />

to market <strong>and</strong> exchange rate volatilityredux<br />

1 This follows from substituting the assumed pricing patterns into the following industry<br />

price index for the foreign country:<br />

⎛<br />

⎞<br />

N +N ∗<br />

1/(1−µ)<br />

P ∗ ∑<br />

= ⎝<br />

1<br />

N + N ∗ p1−µ ⎠<br />

i<br />

.<br />

i=1<br />

2 The key difference is that the term µ(η −1) is replaced with (µ−1)(η −1),because the<br />

exchange rate is no longer exogenous <strong>and</strong> so the dem<strong>and</strong> risk associated with invoicing<br />

in the exporter’s currency has been reduced.<br />

3 For example,in a model with a complete set of state-contingent nominal assets,complete<br />

risk-sharing across markets implies that s t = (P t /u c,t )(u ∗ c,t /P t ).<br />

13 The economics of fixed exchange rates, part 2: speculative<br />

attack models <strong>and</strong> contagion<br />

1 We follow this terminology here,although see Jeanne (2000) for a critique <strong>and</strong> an<br />

alternative taxonomy.<br />

2 For a variant of the first generation model with currency substitution,see Sawada <strong>and</strong><br />

Yotopoulos (2000).<br />

3 As Jeanne (2000) notes,this assumption can be justified by the fact that reserve flows<br />

move very suddenly at the time of an attack <strong>and</strong> this does not leave the authorities much<br />

time to intervene.<br />

4 Obstfeld (1994) provides a rigorous game-theoretic analysis of a speculative attack using<br />

a model with two large speculators.<br />

5 This follows from assuming that αθ 2 /(1 + α) < 1 <strong>and</strong> ruling out speculative bubbles.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!