28.02.2015 Views

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

Exchange Rate Economics: Theories and Evidence

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

334 Speculative attack models <strong>and</strong> contagion<br />

crises but only 3 banking crises. In contrast,in the 1980s <strong>and</strong> 1990s the number of<br />

banking crises quadruples while the number of balance of payments crises hardly<br />

changes.<br />

Using a probit model in which a binary measure (i.e. a 0/1 measure,where<br />

the 1 denotes a crisis <strong>and</strong> is determined by the exchange market pressure variable)<br />

of balance of payments crisis is regressed onto their index of banking crisis they<br />

find that a banking crisis in a country is a significant determinant of a balance of<br />

payments crisis (the converse is not true). Kaminsky <strong>and</strong> Reinhart (1996) then go<br />

on to analyse the evolution of nine macroeconomic variables,18 months before<br />

<strong>and</strong> after the crises,relative to their behaviour in tranquil times. In sum,they find<br />

that balance of payments crises are preceded by recesssions,or below ‘normal’<br />

economic growth. Monetary policy,reacting perhaps to the recessionary forces,<br />

is more expansionary about 6 months before the crises. Finally,the unbacked<br />

liabilities of the financial system climb steeply just before the crises.<br />

Kaminsky et al. (1997) use 15 monthly indicators to provide an alternative<br />

measure of early warning. In particular,when an indicator exceeds a certain<br />

threshold value this is interpreted as a warning signal that a currency crisis may<br />

take place within the following 24 months. The effectiveness of different indicators<br />

is determined on the basis of the following matrix:<br />

Signal performance matrix<br />

Crisis (within 24 months)<br />

Non-crisis (within 24 months)<br />

Signal A B<br />

No Signal C D<br />

Source: Kaminsky et al. (1997).<br />

where A is number of months in which an indicator issued a good signal,B is the<br />

number of months in which an indicator issued a bad signal or simply ‘noise’,C<br />

is the number of months in which an indicator failed to issue (which would have<br />

been a good signal) <strong>and</strong> D is the number of months in which indicator did not issue<br />

a signal (a bad signal). In this context,a perfect indicator would have been one for<br />

which A <strong>and</strong> D > 0,B <strong>and</strong> C = 0. That is,it would issue a signal in every month<br />

that is to be followed by a crisis (A > 0 <strong>and</strong> C = 0) <strong>and</strong> it would not issue a signal<br />

in every month that is not followed by a crisis (B = 0 <strong>and</strong> D > 0). The optimal<br />

threshold for each indicator is then the value which minimises the so-called noise to<br />

signal ratio: [B/B + D] / [A/A + C] which is the ratio between the false signal as a<br />

proportion of the number of months in which false signals could have been issued,<br />

<strong>and</strong> good signals as a proportion of all possible good signals that could have been<br />

issued. Ceteris paribus,the lower is this ratio the better is the indicator. In particular,<br />

a signalling device which issues signals r<strong>and</strong>omly would have a ratio equal to<br />

one <strong>and</strong> therefore Kaminsky et al. (1997) exclude indicators with a ratio of one<br />

<strong>and</strong> above.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!