31.10.2015 Views

ARCHITECTURE

artofinequality_150917_web

artofinequality_150917_web

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

3.1 Contracts<br />

3.1.1<br />

Private property is, substantially, a modern invention.<br />

It was not until the sixteenth century that<br />

Manuel Shvartzberg Carrió<br />

inventing<br />

private landed property began to operate as an individual’s<br />

property:<br />

Real estate is embedded within legal arrangements.<br />

autonomy<br />

exclusive right, whether to be used or to be sold.<br />

It is both determined by and productive of them. In<br />

and selfrealization<br />

At least three main reasons account for this change:<br />

what follows, the reader will find a brief history of<br />

real estate’s relation to the law. This history is necessarily<br />

episodic, because the law itself is composed of<br />

multiple dimensions—pieces of an ever-shifting puzzle<br />

that range from politics and philosophy to media<br />

and finance. It is also episodic because legal frameworks<br />

diverge according to different units of sovereignty;<br />

here, we focus only on the Anglo-American<br />

tradition of Common Law (as opposed to Civil Law),<br />

and only on certain legal actors.<br />

Real estate historically mediates agreements<br />

and disputes over land—a form of power struggle<br />

that has become codified through the law. The central<br />

object of contention is not just land per se, but<br />

the very ontology of land—its status as something<br />

that can be variously possessed by an individual,<br />

traded, speculated upon, or held together by different<br />

political arrangements. Real estate thus has to<br />

be framed alongside legal-philosophical discourses<br />

of the individual’s right to private property, and,<br />

more fundamentally, the modern conception of individuality<br />

as a naturalized condition. Property, personhood,<br />

and market economics together form the<br />

historical-conceptual milieu out of which the field of<br />

real estate emerges.<br />

This field engages diverse agents and actors;<br />

the law provides them with force and stability<br />

through specific legal instruments such as writs,<br />

deeds, statutes, professional accreditations, and, as<br />

discussed here, contracts. Contracts are agreements<br />

between individuals and other entities, and are<br />

thereby the vehicles by which the law’s proper subjects<br />

(including entrepreneurs, tenants, corporations,<br />

or debtors) are recognized and produced. In<br />

turn, legal instruments and actors mediate the expansion<br />

of the market economy across space and<br />

time, requiring the invention of new legal, political,<br />

and financial forms, such as the management of the<br />

future via speculative arrangements of credit, debt,<br />

duty, and desire.<br />

1) the rise of the modern administrative state in lieu<br />

of the monarchical one, 2) the development of a philosophical<br />

doctrine of individual natural rights, 3) the<br />

legal shift from a notion of property tied to customary<br />

obligations to a merely transactional one in the<br />

context of a growing market economy.<br />

Prior to the modern state, landed property was<br />

bound up with the political and social institutions<br />

of monarchical sovereignty. In this arrangement,<br />

the lords who guarded the land administered all its<br />

relationships, including the lives and livelihoods of<br />

those who lived on it. The landlord-tenant relation<br />

was one of extreme inequality, but also of paternalistic<br />

guardianship—land was not a commodity but<br />

the source of subsistence for a stratified community.<br />

Property was thus tied to customary practices<br />

that discharged various social functions—duties and<br />

obligations of moral, economic, and legal nature.<br />

Rather than being individually owned and disposed<br />

of, properties often bore a multiplicity of rights by a<br />

variety of non-exclusive users.<br />

Centuries of struggle, however, traced a shift<br />

in the locus of power: from the singular figure of<br />

the monarch, sovereignty was gradually dispersed<br />

among the many bodies of proto-modern societies,<br />

such as courts and state legislatures. Originally instruments<br />

of a powerful, land-holding elite, these<br />

institutions were reformed in large part to guarantee<br />

the individual property rights of an emerging<br />

bourgeoisie. 2 To this day, property signifies rights in<br />

or to things, not the things themselves. The task of<br />

the state is to enforce these rights as stipulated by<br />

law. 3 Private property, as opposed to public property<br />

(managed by the state) and common property<br />

(for non-exclusive uses), means the right to lawfully<br />

exclude others from an individual’s use of or benefit<br />

from something. As such, it reifies modern notions<br />

of individual autonomy and self-realization defined<br />

against others. This legal-philosophical framework,<br />

originating in the sixteenth century and enshrined in<br />

134 135

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!