31.10.2015 Views

ARCHITECTURE

artofinequality_150917_web

artofinequality_150917_web

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

3.2.4<br />

lative frenzies drive up asset prices to levels unjustified<br />

by profit outlooks, as when the Japanese bubble<br />

of the late 1980s caused “the few hundred acres of<br />

land under the Emperor’s Palace in Tokyo . . . [to be]<br />

worth as much as all the land in Canada or California.”<br />

30 While bubbles can be “exhilarating” for financial<br />

managers, they also pose “ethical challenges”<br />

and legal hazards [See HH: 2011]. 31<br />

The authors’ main theory of bubbles is that<br />

artificial distortions cause the rational self-interest<br />

of financial agents to diverge from that of the shareholders<br />

they are supposed to represent. The global<br />

financial crisis of 2007–09, for example, grew out<br />

of such conflicts of interest: banks, investors, rating<br />

agencies, government corporations, and consumers<br />

all speculated as if there were no risk. The authors<br />

attribute blame for this on the US government’s<br />

backing of mortgage risks. This market intervention<br />

distorted incentives and thus created an “agency<br />

and incentive problem,” where different parties felt<br />

they could safely “out-fool” each other in pursuit of<br />

profits. 32 The second possible reason for bubbles is<br />

the possibility that markets are not efficient. 33 An implication<br />

of this view would be that we as financial<br />

actors are, in the end, irrational.<br />

Urban Economics and Real Estate Markets<br />

(Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall, 1995), 378 pages, $112.80<br />

Denise DiPasquale, President, City Research, formerly Visiting<br />

Assistant Professor at John F. Kennedy School of Government,<br />

Harvard; BA Carnegie Mellon; PhD MIT<br />

William Wheaton, Professor of Economics, MIT; BA Princeton 1968;<br />

PhD University of Pennsylvania 1972<br />

Assigned at: MIT Center for Real Estate, UPenn Wharton<br />

Read by Cezar Nicolescu<br />

DiPasquale and Wheaton’s Urban Economics and<br />

Real Estate Markets use mathematical formulas to<br />

describe urban growth and programming. Beginning<br />

with the question “What is real estate?” the first section<br />

of their book models the relationship between<br />

capital and real estate properties in terms of supply<br />

and demand. The next two sections consider<br />

anticipate<br />

equilibrium<br />

understand<br />

land markets<br />

to predict<br />

value<br />

land in terms of micro and macroeconomics. The<br />

final section assesses questions of regulation and the<br />

public good.<br />

The authors make assumptions that land markets<br />

are efficient due to the fact that tenants are mobile,<br />

and that density reflects land value. At the same<br />

time, changes in transportation technology drive<br />

spatial changes by spurring industrial and residential<br />

diffusion, followed by office and retail spaces.<br />

The book’s “comparative static” equilibrium model<br />

anchors its macroeconomic model in a description<br />

of the real estate market as a web of four interlinked<br />

supply-and-demand relationships. In the asset market,<br />

rents and construction prices rise together, as<br />

do construction prices and construction activity.<br />

In the property market, construction activity and<br />

building stock are also directly related; while rents<br />

and building stock, on the other hand, vary inversely<br />

(housing shortages mean higher rents). As the<br />

economy expands, it exerts a centrifugal pressure<br />

on this equilibrium, with all values increasing in<br />

some measure. 34<br />

Changes in a particular quadrant of the graph<br />

will produce ripple effects. Lower interest rates,<br />

risks, or taxes will cause investors to move funds<br />

into real estate, rotating the rent-price (or asset valuation)<br />

curve counter-clockwise, raising prices. This<br />

will then increase construction activity and building<br />

stock, lowering rents. Conversely, increasing interest<br />

rates or adding onerous regulations will shift the<br />

construction-price (or asset construction) curve left<br />

so as to reduce construction activity, thus raising<br />

prices and rents and lowering stock. 35<br />

The authors explain land value in such disparate<br />

urban areas as New York City, Phoenix, and Tokyo<br />

in terms of a unified theory of land markets. In doing<br />

so, they extend political economist David Ricardo’s<br />

1817 model, which held that demand for land is<br />

elastic and produces relative value, while supply is<br />

inelastic and establishes overall value. This predicts<br />

that land prices will increase closer to employment<br />

centers. Furthermore, different residential groups<br />

will segregate themselves naturally due to unique<br />

158 159

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!