04.04.2013 Views

Governing property, making the modern state - PSI424

Governing property, making the modern state - PSI424

Governing property, making the modern state - PSI424

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

than <strong>the</strong> judgments of <strong>the</strong> sultan’s sheikh-ul-Islam. 46 Birgili’s doctrinal rigour<br />

notwithstanding, it was not his scholastic argument that was to hold sway. Ra<strong>the</strong>r<br />

<strong>the</strong> power of practice and of <strong>the</strong> imperial office of <strong>the</strong> sheikh-ul-Islam was to<br />

define Ottoman Hanafi doctrine on land law.<br />

These debates reveal tensions both practical and ideological.<br />

At a practical level, Birgili’s description of everyday exchanges of land reveals<br />

that <strong>the</strong>re was a kind of market wherein cultivators exchanged <strong>the</strong>ir rights to<br />

lots and drew up contracts governing factors of production such as work in<br />

ploughing, weeding and harvesting. Yet this was a market heavily conditioned<br />

by administrative control over permanent exchanges of lots, subject to a tapu fee<br />

extracted by <strong>the</strong> timari. Thus, as Kemal Paşazade and Birgili <strong>state</strong>, cultivators<br />

and administrators employed terms such as sale and rental when referring to such<br />

contracts, but <strong>the</strong> conditions required by fiqh for such contracts were absent.<br />

At a more ideological level, legal models of right were developed under <strong>the</strong><br />

Mamluks to articulate hierarchically disposed rights. This was what Ibn Qutlubugha<br />

elaborated using <strong>the</strong> vocabulary of lease, and fur<strong>the</strong>r innovations to<br />

contracts of lease were to be introduced under <strong>the</strong> Ottomans concerning rights<br />

in waqf properties. 47 But Ottoman jurisprudence resisted such a conceptualization<br />

for rights in miri land. Thus, <strong>the</strong> timari, or what became <strong>the</strong> standard legal<br />

abstraction, <strong>the</strong> sahib-i arz, acted as an agent or officer of (ra<strong>the</strong>r than co-owner<br />

with) <strong>the</strong> <strong>state</strong>. And what <strong>the</strong> cultivator owed was really tax and not actually<br />

rent, even though he was no more a proprietor than he was a lessee. Moreover,<br />

<strong>the</strong> legal vocabulary in which <strong>the</strong> rights of <strong>the</strong> cultivator were expressed was<br />

composed of terms governing rights to offices not to mülk <strong>property</strong>. 48 Similarly,<br />

<strong>the</strong> devolution of <strong>the</strong> cultivator’s plot from fa<strong>the</strong>r to son(s) follows <strong>the</strong> model<br />

for <strong>the</strong> devolution of office not of mülk <strong>property</strong>. Hence, in many ways Ottoman<br />

jurisprudence treated <strong>the</strong> cultivator more as a quasi-office entailing rights over<br />

objects and produce than as a subject contracting <strong>property</strong> through lease.<br />

In conclusion to this review of <strong>the</strong> central debates of <strong>the</strong> sixteenth century we<br />

may ask why Ottoman jurisprudence did not proceed to <strong>the</strong>orize <strong>the</strong> cultivator’s<br />

legal persona as an office in <strong>the</strong> hierarchy of delegation of powers. Why was such<br />

a definition to remain implicit in <strong>the</strong> terms characterizing <strong>the</strong> cultivator’s rights<br />

to land ra<strong>the</strong>r than being made explicit?<br />

The answer may be political. Ottoman political ideology rested on a distinction<br />

between those who received tax (<strong>the</strong> asker or military, later more generally office<br />

holders, those with a mansıp or vazife) and those who paid tax (<strong>the</strong> reaya or flock:<br />

cultivators, artisans and traders). The administrator (sahib-i arz) was regarded<br />

as an office holder, a deputy of <strong>the</strong> <strong>state</strong> who received tax payments. Ottoman<br />

practice, whereby <strong>the</strong> cultivator paid an entry-fee (resm-i tapu) for his lot and<br />

was subject to <strong>the</strong> approval of <strong>the</strong> administrator for any contracts concerning his<br />

land, proved difficult to legitimate in terms of Islamic conceptions of <strong>property</strong>right.<br />

Likewise, Ottoman administrative practice governing <strong>the</strong> devolution of<br />

<strong>the</strong> cultivator’s plot proved difficult to justify in terms of Islamic jurisprudence.<br />

The practice entailed impartible devolution to son(s), itself <strong>the</strong> pattern for <strong>the</strong><br />

19<br />

Debate in <strong>the</strong> 16th century

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!