07.08.2013 Views

Misrepresentation, Non-Disclosure and Breach ... - Law Commission

Misrepresentation, Non-Disclosure and Breach ... - Law Commission

Misrepresentation, Non-Disclosure and Breach ... - Law Commission

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Applying a compensatory remedy in practice<br />

5.100 Several insurance lawyers expressed concern about how the courts would<br />

determine what an insurer would have done had it known the information. They<br />

thought this would be a particular problem when the insurer would have charged<br />

a higher premium, leading to a proportionate reduction of the claim. Unlike<br />

consumer insurance, there are rarely rating tables to refer to. Instead it was<br />

suggested that each side would bring experts to contradict what the other side<br />

said:<br />

Each side will have an expert each, which will say the opposite of the<br />

other. It’s not as if they all have rating books <strong>and</strong> tariffs… In France, for<br />

example, there are fixed tariffs.<br />

What would actually happen at the box is that we would propose a<br />

premium, <strong>and</strong> the broker would say, ‘Oh, that’s a bit steep. Charlie down<br />

the road does it for half that.’ And they would end up with a number<br />

without any science at all.<br />

5.101 The problems are likely to be greater in relation to business insurance than they<br />

would be for consumer insurance, but we do not see them as insuperable.<br />

However unscientific the negotiations may be, they would be a more accurate<br />

assessment of the loss involved than the current law, which permits avoidance<br />

even though the insurer would have accepted the risk on only slightly different<br />

terms. Of course the insurer may in fact agree to pay something, but the current<br />

law allows unscrupulous insurers to wield a dominant weapon in negotiations.<br />

Are strong incentives required to prevent negligent behaviour?<br />

5.102 A more difficult question is whether in business insurance, where the average<br />

insured is far more likely to be aware of what it should be doing, it is desirable to<br />

create stronger incentives. This was the reason given for refusing to apply the<br />

discretion to refuse rescission under the <strong>Misrepresentation</strong> Act 1967 section 2(2)<br />

to contracts of insurance. If business insureds know that if they make a careless<br />

mistake they will not recover anything under the policy, they have a stronger<br />

incentive to be careful. Insureds may be willing to carry the small increase in<br />

premiums necessary to cover the cost of innocent mistakes as one of the pooled<br />

risks, but be unwilling to “pay for” any part of other insureds’ carelessness. A<br />

business which knows that it is well-run <strong>and</strong> careful may wish to see this reflected<br />

in a lower premium. We invite views on this issue.<br />

Cases where another insurer would have accepted the risk<br />

5.103 For consumers we also asked whether the courts should have an additional<br />

discretion. We suggested this may apply where the insurer would have declined<br />

the risk, but the policyholder’s fault is minor, <strong>and</strong> other insurers would have<br />

accepted the risk at a higher premium. This may also apply where the<br />

misrepresented fact is unrelated to the claim.<br />

5.104 On balance, we think that such a discretion is more appropriate to consumers<br />

than to businesses, but we would welcome advice on the issue.<br />

140

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!