19.04.2014 Views

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

As such, it isn’t surprising that <strong>Argentina</strong> had a bad 20 th century—it just reverted to form. In a<br />

sense, the other hypotheses can be understood as explaining the channels through which<br />

<strong>Argentina</strong>’s lack of early 20 th century resources resulted in less economic development.<br />

Bad Politics, Bad Policies<br />

There is some dispute as to whether <strong>Argentina</strong> was behind other advanced countries in 1900 in<br />

the state of its political development. Its policies, which seem to have preserved a reasonable<br />

amount of rule of law <strong>and</strong> which allowed free trade in goods, capital <strong>and</strong> people, seem to have<br />

been quite benign. Politically, <strong>Argentina</strong> was a republic, albeit one with a limited franchise until<br />

1912, <strong>and</strong> strongly empowered local l<strong>and</strong>owners. But there is no question that <strong>Argentina</strong> had<br />

significant political instability over the 20 th century, <strong>and</strong> enacted many policies that seem to have<br />

been harmful for growth. The second hypothesis is that these problems are responsible for<br />

<strong>Argentina</strong>’s economic malaise.<br />

It is perhaps useful to briefly describe the historical context for such political instability. An<br />

important event is the 1916 election of Hipolito Yrigoyen, which replaced the conservative<br />

regime by the Radical party, <strong>and</strong> also brought into the country’s political life a large portion of<br />

the middle class. This was the beginning of a dramatic change in the way the country would be<br />

governed. The Radicales would wield power until 1930. While it is true that Yrigoyen enacted<br />

some policies, like minimum wage laws, that some economists would argue are detrimental to<br />

growth, there is little evidence that <strong>Argentina</strong> suffered during this period. The real watershed<br />

seems to have been in 1930, when a military coup brought down Yrigoyen’s second government.<br />

<strong>Argentina</strong>’s “returned to democracy” with the 1931 election, where the radicals were banned<br />

from participating. As the great depression impacted world trade, a more conservative regime<br />

was put in place by an elite-dominated coalition known as the “Concordancia”. It soon began<br />

<strong>Argentina</strong>’s turn inward by implementing more interventionist policies: public works were<br />

started, import duties were increased <strong>and</strong> a system of multiple exchange rates favored industrial<br />

activities (over agriculture). The resulting industrial growth led to some migration of rural<br />

workers to urban centers <strong>and</strong> to a changing composition of labor organizations. Real wages<br />

remained stagnant while the perception of concessions to foreign trading partners, principally<br />

Britain, irked nationalist sentiment.<br />

A 1943 military coup named Juan Domingo Perón to the hitherto harmless post of secretary of<br />

labor <strong>and</strong> social welfare. From there, Perón enacted a comprehensive set of pro-labor laws that<br />

included a scheme to establish <strong>and</strong> periodically adjust minimum wages, often leading to<br />

increases in real terms; yearly paid vacations; retirement <strong>and</strong> health insurance benefits; <strong>and</strong> an<br />

annual m<strong>and</strong>atory bonus equal to an additional month’s salary. He also instituted the Agricultural<br />

Worker Statute (Estatuto del Peon) in late 1944, which outlined the specific rights <strong>and</strong><br />

obligations of both rural workers <strong>and</strong> employers <strong>and</strong> was perceived as a defiance of the l<strong>and</strong>ed<br />

elite. In 1945, he enacted the Law on Professional Associations, which gave his Labor<br />

Secretariat veto power on the formation of new unions. By the end of his tenure, <strong>Argentina</strong> had<br />

advanced to a world leader in labor legislation (see for example, the description in D’Abate,<br />

1983). The nine years of Perón’s presidency starting in 1946 witnessed intense political<br />

polarization. Perón enacted policies that eventually antagonized the rich. He continued a set of<br />

pro-union policies: between 1946 <strong>and</strong> 1954, union membership increased from 880,000 to 2.5<br />

million, which represented 42.5% of all workers (see for example, Smith, 1991). He also

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!