19.04.2014 Views

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Maddison's "Western Offshoots" by less than 20% −<strong>and</strong> sometimes by as little as 7%− between<br />

1905 <strong>and</strong> 1929. Massive population growth <strong>and</strong> economic success combined to multiply by 4<br />

<strong>Argentina</strong>'s share in world GDP between 1870 <strong>and</strong> 1930. 1<br />

<strong>Di</strong>sheartening <strong>and</strong> disappointing as <strong>Argentina</strong>'s post-1930 performance was, does it really<br />

involve an economic puzzle? Is there any reason to believe that a country that has reached the<br />

league of the rich should remain there, or even approach the richest among the rich? The<br />

question has an empirical <strong>and</strong> a theoretical side to it. Let's formulate the empirical question with<br />

some precision. For example: are there many other examples of countries which, after reaching<br />

at some point at least 80% of the per capita GDP of the twelve originally rich 2 , subsequently fell<br />

to a level consistently below 50%, as <strong>Argentina</strong> did? The list is short, <strong>and</strong> has the peculiarity that<br />

all five cases hovered around 40% of that sample by the year 2000: Uruguay (around 100% in<br />

the 1870s), plus four oil exporters: Venezuela (more than 100% in 1945-1960), Saudi Arabia<br />

(90% during the first oil shock), Kuwait <strong>and</strong> Qatar (both of them, more than 400% in the early<br />

1950s). Three of the five are tiny, with a population less than a tenth of <strong>Argentina</strong>'s. In all five<br />

cases, the high per capita GDP at their summit is definitely due to an exceptionally high<br />

availability of natural resources per person, including not only the oil exporters but also the<br />

213,000 Uruguayans who held, each, an average of 24 cattle <strong>and</strong> 12 sheep in 1860 3 .<br />

Was that also the case for <strong>Argentina</strong>? In the next section we discuss that possibility as part of one<br />

of the hypotheses for <strong>Argentina</strong>'s decline, namely, that <strong>Argentina</strong>'s per capita GDP during the<br />

initial decades of the 20th century was a misleading indicator of its real wealth − in particular,<br />

that GDP was more related to l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> less to physical <strong>and</strong> human capital than was the case for<br />

countries of similar income per head. We leave the full discussion of that hypothesis for the<br />

following section <strong>and</strong> for some of the articles in this volume, but it is interesting to pursue at this<br />

point the theoretical aspects of economic growth as applied to countries in which the stream of<br />

income springs, to a larger extent than the norm, from natural resources. Is there, in the<br />

neoclassical theory of economic growth, anything special going on in countries with a high ratio<br />

of natural resources to population?<br />

If we define modern economies as those where accumulation of capital −physical <strong>and</strong> human−<br />

<strong>and</strong> technology account for all of the growth in per capita GDP, a corollary of Solow-type<br />

models is the prediction of "conditional convergence": countries with lower per capita stocks of<br />

human <strong>and</strong> physical capital are poorer; other things equal, in countries with lower stocks of both<br />

types of capital marginal productivity is higher, due to decreasing returns; then, if "institutional<br />

incentives" <strong>and</strong> other traits −such as propensities to save− are similar, poorer countries should<br />

grow faster than richer ones 4 . What are the implications of neoclassical growth theory for<br />

1 All data from Maddison, in http://www.ggdc.net/maddison/, retrieved March 2010.<br />

2 Ie., the richest in 1900, a group including Engl<strong>and</strong>, France, Germany, their economic hinterl<strong>and</strong> (Denmark,<br />

Belgium, Netherl<strong>and</strong>s, Switzerl<strong>and</strong>, Austria) plus the four "Western Offshoots" (USA, Canada, Australia <strong>and</strong> New<br />

Zeal<strong>and</strong>). The thirteenth was <strong>Argentina</strong> (77,7% of the richest twelve), <strong>and</strong>, after a gap, Uruguay (62,5%), Sweden<br />

(62,3%) <strong>and</strong> Chile (61,7%) followed.<br />

3 Uruguayan population in 1860: extrapolation from Maddison's data for 1850 <strong>and</strong> 1870 using a constant rate of<br />

growth. Cattle <strong>and</strong> sheep from Gran Enciclopedia Rialp, 1991.<br />

4 In addition, there could be some "technological catch up" as improving the backward technology of poorer<br />

countries requires the cheap expedient (of copy-pasting foreign techniques, rather than the more expensive process<br />

of developing new technologies.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!