19.04.2014 Views

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

has a comparative advantage in the production of agricultural goods. Thus, it might or might not<br />

produce manufactured goods. It also produces services. We assume that the agricultural good is<br />

produced in the primary sector using l<strong>and</strong> <strong>and</strong> capital, while the manufactured good is produced in<br />

the secondary sector using labor <strong>and</strong> capital. Services are produced using labor only. We also<br />

assume that capital moves between the primary <strong>and</strong> secondary sectors more slowly than labor<br />

moves between the secondary <strong>and</strong> tertiary sectors. This gives rise to three different time horizons:<br />

the short run (no factor reallocation), the medium run (only labor adjusts) <strong>and</strong> the long run (full<br />

reallocation).<br />

We show that import-substitution policies exhibit path dependence. Indeed, this is a very<br />

important insight in underst<strong>and</strong>ing the economic history of <strong>Argentina</strong>. We also use our model to<br />

characterize the dem<strong>and</strong>s for protectionist policies of the different groups in the economy. In the<br />

short run, l<strong>and</strong>owners, capitalists who have invested in the primary sector <strong>and</strong> workers employed<br />

in the tertiary sector support free-trade policies. On the other h<strong>and</strong>, capitalists <strong>and</strong> workers in the<br />

secondary sector support protectionist policies. In the medium run, workers behave as a group <strong>and</strong><br />

will support protectionist policies if the industrial sector is sufficiently developed (i.e., the<br />

secondary sector employs enough labor <strong>and</strong> capital). In the long run, workers will support free<br />

trade if the terms of trade are favorable enough.<br />

Using the insights derived from our model, we then argue that much of the distributional conflict<br />

that arose was among owners of different production inputs <strong>and</strong> that trade policies were widely<br />

used to shift income across groups. At the beginning of the century, factor allocation resembled<br />

what we call "specialization <strong>and</strong> trade." During the inter-war period, trade opportunities <strong>and</strong> the<br />

terms of trade worsened, which led to an incipient industrialization process. <strong>Argentina</strong> started the<br />

second half of the century with a very different economic configuration, as industrialization had<br />

come a long way in terms of what we refer to as diversification <strong>and</strong> trade. These new economic<br />

conditions also changed the political equilibrium. Urban workers employed in the manufacturing<br />

sector <strong>and</strong> industrialists were now major social actors who dem<strong>and</strong>ed that the industrialization<br />

process be deepened, which hurt trade <strong>and</strong> took the economy close to autarky. The years that<br />

followed the Second World War witnessed an extraordinary expansion of trade in which <strong>Argentina</strong><br />

was not an active participant. We contend that one important reason behind this outcome was the<br />

set of protectionist policies that were enacted in the years following that war <strong>and</strong> that the main<br />

supporters of these policies were the new political forces that emerged from the industrialization<br />

process in the inter-war period.<br />

The second half of the century was characterized by a strong distributional conflict centered on<br />

trade policy. Traditional sectors composed of owners of factors employed in the primary sector<br />

supported free-trade policies, whereas the newer political forces supported protectionism <strong>and</strong><br />

import substitution. <strong>Argentina</strong> embarked on an ambitious process of import substitution that aimed<br />

at achieving self-sufficiency, especially in activities deemed strategic, such as oil <strong>and</strong> steel. As<br />

domestically produced goods were substituted for labor-intensive imported manufactures, the<br />

industrial sector grew <strong>and</strong> drew inputs from other sectors. The substitution of capital-intensive<br />

activities was more problematic. Some of these activities were not profitable even though they had<br />

a captive internal market. With little regard for economic rationality, the government took an<br />

active role in developing these activities through public enterprises that became a chronic source<br />

of deficits.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!