19.04.2014 Views

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

for the years to come. The most important government intervention during the period 1945-1975<br />

was the introduction of a relative price system which favored industry (<strong>and</strong> particularly<br />

labor-intensive industry) at the expense of the agricultural sector. As a consequence, internal<br />

relative prices diverged from international market prices, thus generating a sharp differential<br />

(which put the agricultural sector at a disadvantage) between the internal <strong>and</strong> external terms of<br />

trade (see Díaz-Alej<strong>and</strong>ro, 1970, <strong>and</strong> Mallon <strong>and</strong> Sourrouille, 1975). The triumph of the<br />

industrialization model under a closed economy, over time, <strong>and</strong> even after the demise of Perón, led<br />

to the adoption of a scheme of industrial integration which consisted of completing every step of<br />

the production process, from capital goods <strong>and</strong> inputs to final goods, inside the country's borders,<br />

in evident contradiction with the post-war tendency of developed countries, whose trade was <strong>and</strong><br />

continues to be mainly intra-industry (see <strong>Llach</strong>, 2002).<br />

Behind these economic policy decisions, there was an alliance of economic <strong>and</strong> political interests<br />

formed by unions, industrialists <strong>and</strong> the armed forces. Unions consolidated their power by<br />

delivering better wages, working conditions <strong>and</strong> social protection to their members. Industrialists<br />

had achieved a considerable level of protection from competition. Finally, the military took the<br />

development of the steel <strong>and</strong> oil industries under its wing. Although this alliance was evidently<br />

born after the Peronist years, it had sufficient resilience to last even through the military<br />

governments <strong>and</strong> the periods of political proscription of Peronism (see, among others, Halperín<br />

Donghi, 1994, <strong>and</strong> <strong>Llach</strong>, 2002). 12<br />

Up to now we have been assuming that the economy operated near the efficiency frontier. This is<br />

reasonable if we assume that capital allocation <strong>and</strong> employment decisions were made in a<br />

decentralized way by profit-maximizing agents. However, during Peronism <strong>and</strong> the years that<br />

followed until the collapse of the import-substitution model, that assumption is hard to maintain.<br />

Capital was allocated on the basis of political rather than economic considerations. Labor<br />

allocation was no less distorted: public employment was used as a means of combatting<br />

unemployment; moreover, unions regulated quantities <strong>and</strong> prices in their members' labor markets<br />

to the extent that they were politically able to do so.<br />

Not surprisingly, income redistribution <strong>and</strong> industrial promotion policies rapidly ran up against a<br />

formidable constraint: exports stagnated (see Brambilla et al. in this volume). It is true that the<br />

stagnation of Argentine exports can be partly attributed to the global closure of markets <strong>and</strong> to the<br />

protectionist policies applied by industrial countries in agriculture that favored self-sufficiency<br />

(especially in Europe). However, it is also true that <strong>Argentina</strong> underperformed even in comparison<br />

to other countries that shared the same markets.<br />

<strong>Argentina</strong> accounted for more than one third of all Latin American exports in 1928, one fourth in<br />

1938 <strong>and</strong> only one eighth in 1954. It exported mainly primary goods: corn, wheat, linen, wool <strong>and</strong><br />

meat. The joint share of these five agricultural goods in world trade declined from 8.6% in<br />

1926-1929 to 3.9% in 1960. Nevertheless, the fact that <strong>Argentina</strong>'s market share was halved during<br />

that period provides evidence of <strong>Argentina</strong>'s decline relative to other agricultural exporters.<br />

Overall, if we consider the world exports of these five primary products, <strong>Argentina</strong> accounted for<br />

1.8% of those exports in the late 1920s <strong>and</strong> for only 0.4% in 1960. If we analyze export trends by<br />

12 This alliance was very effective at maintaining <strong>and</strong> obtaining new rents from the state (see Mallon <strong>and</strong> Sourrouille,<br />

1975).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!