19.04.2014 Views

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

Exceptional Argentina Di Tella, Glaeser and Llach - Thomas Piketty

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Clearly, world market conditions were more favorable to <strong>Argentina</strong> in 1943-1955 than in<br />

1929-1943. After the war, policymakers had an option which they had not had during the Great<br />

Depression: to guide economic growth on the basis of exp<strong>and</strong>ing exports of both rural <strong>and</strong><br />

manufactured products (see Díaz-Alej<strong>and</strong>ro, 1970). Indeed, this was explicitly attempted under the<br />

economic leadership of Federico Pinedo during the early 1940s. Pinedo's plan was a well<br />

thought-out attempt to recover the dynamism of the agricultural sector <strong>and</strong> to promote export-led<br />

industrialization (see <strong>Llach</strong>, 2002). However, Pinedo's strategy failed to take hold. One of the<br />

reasons for this failure is that it was opposed by the new dominant electoral coalition formed by<br />

urban capitalists <strong>and</strong> workers, who stood to benefit from a deepening of the import-substitution<br />

strategy (see Section 3.3). This electoral coalition would elect Juan Perón as President of the<br />

country in 1946 in what were arguably the first truly free <strong>and</strong> democratic elections with universal<br />

male suffrage.<br />

Perón decided to consolidate the social base of his movement by redistributing income to the<br />

working classes. In fact, he saw industrialization as a mean of achieving the goals of his<br />

nationalistic <strong>and</strong> populist policy of increasing the real consumption, employment <strong>and</strong> economic<br />

security of the masses of workers (see Gerchunoff, 1989).<br />

Indeed, as Figure 5 shows, the share of wages on GDP peaked during the Peronist era. It is clear<br />

from the figure that the share of wages in GDP is lower when the economy is integrated into the<br />

international economy than under autarky when the secondary sector has exhausted its<br />

possibilities of import substitution. Notice that this stylized fact is consistent with our model. In<br />

the long-run equilibrium workers' share is equal to ( 1−<br />

φ a<br />

−φ<br />

m<br />

) + ( 1−<br />

β )( Y m<br />

/ GDP)<br />

, i.e., the share<br />

of services in consumer preferences plus the share of labor in the secondary sector times the share<br />

of industrial output in total GDP. Notice that in the long run, <strong>and</strong> perhaps even in the medium run,<br />

workers not necessarily are better off under autarky (see Section 3.3 <strong>and</strong> Proposition 7).

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!