26.04.2016 Views

SHAPING THE FUTURE HOW CHANGING DEMOGRAPHICS CAN POWER HUMAN DEVELOPMENT

1VPo4Vw

1VPo4Vw

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

38<br />

Having fewer<br />

dependents on<br />

working-age<br />

people encourages<br />

accelerated<br />

economic growth<br />

come at a hefty price, such as through health-endangering<br />

air pollution and the generation of<br />

greater amounts of waste.<br />

The Republic of Korea provides an example<br />

of managing demographic transition to advance<br />

human development. As the country’s birth rate<br />

declined in the mid-1960s, elementary school<br />

enrolment fell, which released funds. The Government<br />

invested these in improving the quality<br />

of education at higher levels to equip the growing<br />

working-age population with marketable skills,<br />

and fostered economic growth to create more<br />

jobs through strategic investments. Essentially,<br />

the Republic of Korea used its demographic<br />

window to educate its population, including<br />

women, and to integrate them successfully into<br />

the labour market, leading to rapid economic<br />

growth and higher standards of living across<br />

its population.<br />

Broadly speaking, to reap demographic dividends<br />

and transform these into greater human<br />

development, patterns of public investment need<br />

to respond to demographic changes. Countries<br />

with a very youthful population need to invest<br />

more in schools; those with a large working-age<br />

population need to create large numbers of decent<br />

jobs; and those with an extensive elderly<br />

population need to invest more in health, transportation<br />

and other public facilities, as well as<br />

old-age pension systems.<br />

TWO TYPES OF DIVIDENDS<br />

Demographic change offers two potential dividends,<br />

which can be significant. 47 The first<br />

demographic dividend occurs when fertility<br />

rates fall and the labour force grows more rapidly<br />

than the dependent population. This builds on<br />

a simple equation: more labour equals more<br />

economic output, assuming no major drag from<br />

unemployment or underemployment.<br />

A second demographic dividend unfolds as<br />

transition proceeds if the larger number of workers<br />

is also more productive. This comes about in<br />

part through investments in human capabilities,<br />

such as through health and education, that, for<br />

instance, allow people to do more skilled jobs.<br />

Over time, they can then earn more, save more<br />

and acquire more assets such as homes, land<br />

and businesses.<br />

Both demographic dividends can translate<br />

into economic and human development gains.<br />

They are roughly sequential, with the first<br />

lasting for three to five decades depending on<br />

the speed at which fertility declines. The second<br />

begins later, can be sustained for a longer<br />

period and may be larger. Some overlap may<br />

occur, and neither dividend is automatic, with<br />

demographic transition merely opening a window<br />

of opportunity.<br />

The first dividend declines as population<br />

ageing sets in, and links to economic growth<br />

then tend to diverge for the second dividend.<br />

High-income countries have experienced this,<br />

and soon many middle-income countries will do<br />

so as well. Expenditure on health care rises as<br />

infectious diseases retreat and chronic, degenerative<br />

non-communicable diseases dominate,<br />

for instance. The ability to manage changes<br />

like these rests largely on the shoulders of the<br />

workforce, and its capacity for productive work,<br />

backed by a sufficient supply of decent employment<br />

options. Even if the number of workers<br />

falls relative to the number of dependents, they<br />

may be much more productive than a larger, less<br />

educated workforce. 48<br />

MEASURING IMPACTS<br />

OF DEMOGRAPHIC CHANGE<br />

Early thinking around the impacts of demographic<br />

transition focused heavily on the contributions<br />

of the demographic dividend to economic<br />

growth. As far back as 1958, a study of India and<br />

Mexico found high costs from large shares of<br />

young and old dependents in a given population.<br />

Savings rates for families with a large number of<br />

children were lower, and requirements for social<br />

spending on health, education and so on were<br />

great. Productive capital per person was more<br />

limited. The study suggested that declines in<br />

fertility, by lessening dependency burdens on<br />

working-age people, could free them for activities<br />

that promote economic growth. 49<br />

In the last two decades, a number of studies<br />

have estimated demographic dividends. One covering<br />

the years from 1965 to 1990 suggested that<br />

25 percent to 40 percent of East Asia’s economic<br />

miracle, defined as an increase in per capita<br />

income, could be attributed to demographic<br />

transition. 50 Another on China calculated that,<br />

from 1980 to 2000, changes in age structure

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!