15.12.2012 Views

Chapter 2

Chapter 2

Chapter 2

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

of resource allocation) to underestimate expenditure, so avoiding expansion of expenditure<br />

that may not be appropriate.<br />

On duplication, it should be added that the composition of public expenditure (in the<br />

sense of the ratio between services supplied directly by public provider and those supplied<br />

by private ones) seems to produce a non neutral effect. Specifically, one finds a<br />

positive correlation between total expenditure and the “outsourced” share, though this<br />

phenomenon is limited to the Regions of the Centre-South of Italy. In other words, the<br />

composition of public/private supply is not in itself a discriminating factor, except where<br />

an apparently poor planning configures system inefficiencies.<br />

The econometric analysis provides other information of some interest. For example, it<br />

confirms that the Northern Regions display a basic homogeneity in expenditure behaviour,<br />

whereas the Centre-South constitutes an aggregation of “monads”, with internal<br />

differences yet to be fully explained.<br />

Finally, the model also makes it possible to quantify the effects of redistribution produced<br />

by the solidarity implied by the universal coverage granted by the SSN. The effects<br />

are significant in both size and characteristics. The Northern Regions “renounce” a share<br />

of expenditure that may reach or exceed 15% in favour of the Regions of the South that<br />

may record expenditure 50% higher than would be the case in the absence of solidarity.<br />

This lets one realize the extent to which full attainment of federalism in health care is an<br />

uphill task.<br />

Quantitatively, the model assumes an increase in total expenditure faster than that in<br />

GDP, though for 2007 this phenomena is limited by a significant real growth of the last.<br />

The expenditures should reach a level equal to 8,2%-8,3% of GDP 2 , thus remaining<br />

below the present European average.<br />

The impact on households is limited, since the growth in public resources made available<br />

is counterbalanced by the new (higher) co-payments.<br />

We expect a decrease the burden on household budget of about 6-12%. Nevertheless,<br />

the action aimed at imposing greater responsibility on patients, involves a complex equitative<br />

impact. The adoption of a lump-sum payment on specialist’s prescriptions, lets us<br />

presume an unfair impact on households, especially for those most at risk (see chapter<br />

4.1, Doglia, Spandonaro).<br />

4 The economic scenario: efficiency improvement<br />

The measurement of efficiency (leaving aside merely anecdotal evidence, useful as that may<br />

be) is notoriously difficult, especially in a sector of such complexity as that of health care.<br />

Coherent management of the system also requires keeping apart purely financial actions<br />

and those intended to raise the overall efficiency of the system.<br />

According to Fioravanti and Spandonaro (see chapter 3.1), joining analysis of regional<br />

financial policies (ex-ante) and of their results (ex-post) it emerges that the Regions are<br />

strongly conditioned by the requirement to obtain short term savings.<br />

2 The model uses ISTAT and Ministry of Health data. The level of expenditure cited is approximately consistent with a level<br />

of 8,5%, according to the OECD Health Data standard (see chapter 1.1).<br />

[23]<br />

CEIS Health Report 2006

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!