14.12.2012 Views

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Controlling <strong>for</strong> in<strong>for</strong>mation problems<br />

The provision of sufficient in<strong>for</strong>mation was ensured through the measures<br />

outlined above to limit inequality. In addition, local authorities made in<strong>for</strong>mation<br />

as easy to access as possible and offered support in analysing in<strong>for</strong>mation if<br />

requested to reduce the burden of choice on the user.<br />

Per<strong>for</strong>mance in practice 134<br />

If insufficient in<strong>for</strong>mation was available or the burden of choice too great <strong>for</strong><br />

rational choices to be made, we would expect to see this reflected in a lack of<br />

searching and bidding behaviour. Available evidence on consumers’ willingness<br />

to bear search costs is positive, with one pilot surveying applicants and finding<br />

that 85 per cent of respondents were looking in the paper every week <strong>for</strong> adverts.<br />

However, most pilots that examined the issue suggest that whilst many<br />

participants were actively searching <strong>for</strong> properties, bidding was relatively<br />

infrequent. For example, one pilot analysed bidding behaviour over 15 cycles<br />

and determined that the majority of people bid infrequently. Out of a maximum<br />

of 30 possible bids, it found that only 7 per cent bid more than 20 times and more<br />

than 25 per cent bid only once or twice. Most pilots reported that between 25 and<br />

50 per cent of applicants were bidding at any one time. However, this could have<br />

been a result of lack of suitable properties rather than an unwillingness to bear<br />

the costs of bidding per se.<br />

Outcome of market mechanism<br />

BENEFITS<br />

Section 10 – Choice-<strong>Based</strong> Letting in Social Housing<br />

Theory suggests that introducing choice could have the effect of increasing<br />

efficiency through both the demand and supply sides of the market. As noted in<br />

Part III, there are three main types of efficiency relevant to our analysis of user<br />

choice, namely allocative, productive and dynamic efficiency. The first of these,<br />

allocative efficiency, refers to a situation in which scarce resources are allocated<br />

to the use that society values higher than all other alternative uses. In other<br />

words, resources are allocated in a way that maximises social welfare. In this<br />

situation, no one member of society can be made better off by re-allocating<br />

resources without making another worse off. Productive efficiency is a precondition<br />

<strong>for</strong> allocative efficiency, and is achieved when a specific outcome or<br />

level of output is obtained using the most cost-effective method. Dynamic<br />

efficiency refers to the efficient allocation of resources over time.<br />

Introducing user choice can also lead to increases in social welfare, both by<br />

improving efficiency and by empowering users. Reducing the dependency of<br />

users on housing officials can be beneficial in its own rights, and can improve<br />

customer satisfaction by conferring on users a sense of ownership of the<br />

134 All data in this paragraph taken from Marsh et al (2004), Op.Cit., p.136.<br />

135

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!