14.12.2012 Views

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Due to the negative externality, these taxes can provide a source of public<br />

revenue that is likely to be less distortionary than existing taxes. 52 In fact, Terkla<br />

estimates that revenues from an effluent fee charged on particulates and sulphur<br />

oxide emissions would provide substantial efficiency gains of up to $3.05 billion<br />

(in 1982 US dollars) if substituted <strong>for</strong> either federal individual income tax or<br />

corporation income tax. 53<br />

APPLICATIONS<br />

Unit taxes in the <strong>for</strong>m of effluent fees have been employed to regulate water quality<br />

and noise pollution in Europe. However, their goal has largely been to raise money<br />

to finance projects <strong>for</strong> water quality management rather than to regulate optimal<br />

effluent discharge. Evidence from the Netherlands, however, suggests that fees<br />

have had a measurable effect on reducing emissions. For example, Bressers (1983)<br />

and Brown and Bressers (1986) use econometric techniques to find that firms have<br />

responded to fees by cutting back significantly on discharges of water borne<br />

pollutants. 54 Although a command and control situation would also have reduced<br />

pollution, the benefit of the taxes and subsidy system is that the cost of the<br />

pollution is internalised and the market adjusts to find the optimum level of output.<br />

WHEN ARE TAXES PREFERABLE TO MARKETABLE PERMITS?<br />

Section 7 – <strong>Market</strong>-<strong>Based</strong> Mechanisms<br />

In a world of perfect in<strong>for</strong>mation and certainty, tradable permits and taxes would<br />

have identical effects on emissions abatement and costs. 55 In the real world,<br />

however, uncertainties about costs and benefits can influence which approach is<br />

preferred. For instance, in cases where a small increase in the level of emissions<br />

could result in a large decrease in benefit a tradable permit approach may be<br />

preferred. In cases where the cost of achieving a given emissions level is<br />

uncertain the charge approach may be preferred. 56<br />

52 Lee, D. and Misiolek, W. (1986) ‘Substituting Pollution Taxation <strong>for</strong> General Taxation: Some Implications <strong>for</strong><br />

Efficiency in Pollution Taxation’, Journal of Environmental Economic Management 13(4).<br />

53 Terkla, D. (1984) ‘The Efficiency Value of Effluent Tax Revenues’, Journal of Environmental Economic<br />

Management 11(2).<br />

54 Bressers, H. (1983) ‘The Effectiveness of Dutch Water Quality <strong>Policy</strong>,’ Mimeo, The Netherlands: Twente University<br />

of Technology.<br />

Brown, G. and H. Bressers (1986) ‘Evidence Supporting Effluent Charges’, Mimeo. The Netherlands: Twente<br />

University of Technology.<br />

55 <strong>Using</strong> taxes to address environmental externalities leads to an efficient level of pollution abatement, which can<br />

occurred at the lowest marginal cost. Baumol,W.J.(1972) ‘On taxation and the Control of Externalities’, American<br />

Economic Review 62 (3).<br />

56 See <strong>for</strong> instance Stavins, R. (2001) ‘Lessons from the American Experiment with <strong>Market</strong>-based Environmental<br />

Policies’ RFF discussion paper 01-53: and Chairman of the Council of Economic Advisors (2000), Making <strong>Market</strong><br />

Work <strong>for</strong> the Environment, Economic Report of the President, Chapter 7. USA 2000<br />

63

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!