14.12.2012 Views

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

As Stonecash and Jensen (2004) observe, if the private sector were inherently<br />

more efficient than the public sector, outsourcing to private firms should result<br />

in larger savings than services outsourced to an in-house team. However, the<br />

balance of evidence shows that observed outsourcing savings are achieved<br />

whether the service provider winning the contract is public or private. 29 These<br />

savings come both from better management of resources and higher<br />

productivity of inputs, and in some cases also from lower wages <strong>for</strong> staff. 30<br />

Moreover, other studies have shown that simply changing from public to private<br />

ownership may yield little efficiency benefits if competition is not introduced at<br />

the same time. 31 Together this all suggests that it is the introduction of<br />

competition that leads to greater efficiency.<br />

The introduction of ex ante competition <strong>for</strong> the market<br />

Some services can be characterised as natural monopolies as the characteristics<br />

of demand and supply mean that they may be most efficiently supplied by one<br />

supplier. For example, on rural bus routes there may be insufficient demand to<br />

support more than one provider, or indeed in some circumstances the route may<br />

only be profitable at all with a subsidy. In such cases, where it is not possible to<br />

have competition ‘in’ the market, the use of tendering may make it possible to<br />

have competition ‘<strong>for</strong>’ the market where rival firms bid <strong>for</strong> the right to run the<br />

monopoly service. 32 Although this ex-ante competition is not a total substitute<br />

<strong>for</strong> competition ‘in’ the market, in circumstances where competition in the<br />

market is not possible it can yield many of its benefits. For example, it may not<br />

be economic to have two competing bus operators on a local bus route.<br />

However, by allowing competing companies to compete <strong>for</strong> the right to provide<br />

the monopoly service, some of the monopoly profits can be recouped ex-ante.<br />

In addition, this could be combined with limits on fares to prevent the<br />

exploitation of monopoly power.<br />

APPLICATIONS<br />

Section 7 – <strong>Market</strong>-<strong>Based</strong> Mechanisms<br />

Competitive tendering can be used in situations where a government obligation<br />

to provide a particular service can be separated from the actual delivery of the<br />

service. This has been used in a number of applications ranging from cleaning<br />

29 Domberger et al. (1995) ‘The determinants of price and quality in competitively tendered contracts’, Economic<br />

Journal. This study looks at contracts <strong>for</strong> cleaning services awarded through competitive tender, comparing those<br />

tendered with those not tendered, and those contracted out with those won by the in-house team. Domberger et<br />

al find it is the tendering of the contract <strong>for</strong> competition that leads to observed reductions in price, and conclude<br />

that contracting out rather than awarding contracts to an in-house team has a negligible impact on both price and<br />

quality; Domberger, Meadowcroft and Thompson (1986) ‘Competitive tendering and efficiency: the case of refuse<br />

collection’ Fiscal Studies 8. This paper reports similar conclusions with respect to refuse collection, as savings<br />

from introducing competition through the tender process are of a similar order whether the contract is awarded<br />

to a private contractor or the in-house team.<br />

30 Cubbin, J. Domberger, S. and Meadowcroft, S. (1986) ‘Competitive tendering and refuse collection: identifying the<br />

sources of efficiency gains’, Fiscal Studies 8.<br />

31 Pollitt per<strong>for</strong>ms a social cost benefit analysis of the Scottish electricity generating companies and finds negligible<br />

benefits. He suggests that this is due to the lack of restructuring as remaining vertically integrated may have<br />

impeded entry by competitors into the home market. Pollitt, M. (1999) ‘The restructuring and privatisation of the<br />

electricity supply industry in Scotland’, Mimeo.<br />

32 Demsetz, H. (1968) ‘Why regulate utilities?’, Journal of Law and Economics.<br />

45

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!