14.12.2012 Views

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Public</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: <strong>Using</strong> <strong>Market</strong>-<strong>Based</strong> <strong>Approaches</strong><br />

Incomplete contracts<br />

Ideally, when a service is contracted out to the private sector, the contract should<br />

specify not just the price but also the quality of service to be provided. In<br />

practice, however, it may be difficult to specify quality criteria that are<br />

comprehensive and capable of measurement. This can lead providers to<br />

sacrifice quality in order to minimise costs, or to focus only on measures of<br />

quality that can easily be measured. In general, contracting out will work best<br />

where the opportunities to reduce costs through reducing quality are small or<br />

the effect on quality can be easily measured.<br />

Partly this issue can be addressed by ensuring that contracts have well specified<br />

measures of quality, which are effectively monitored and en<strong>for</strong>ced, although it<br />

may not always be possible to devise and implement such measures. This can<br />

be rein<strong>for</strong>ced, however, if firms know that the quality of the service they provide<br />

(broadly defined) will affect whether they are successful in future tenders. This<br />

can create incentives to maintain quality standards even where they are not<br />

specified in the contract.<br />

Hold-up problem<br />

A related issue is the ‘hold-up’ problem. This problem occurs in contracts when<br />

an initial commitment by one party exposes it to ex post opportunism by the<br />

other. For example, when a contractor considers whether to undertake a large<br />

investment in a specific asset, it will take into account the incentives <strong>for</strong> the<br />

official managing the contract to renegotiate prices down once the investment<br />

has been undertaken. If the investment is irreversible and has no alternative use<br />

outside the public sector, the government could theoretically ‘hold-up’ the<br />

contractor and capture the entire benefits of the investment <strong>for</strong> itself without<br />

paying an appropriate transfer fee. This is a problem arising from incomplete<br />

contracts because, if the government could credibly commit to not acting in this<br />

manner, the contractor would face the correct incentives when making his<br />

investment decisions. However, where such commitment is not possible, the<br />

contractor will be aware of the potential <strong>for</strong> hold-up and consequently invest<br />

less.<br />

Asymmetric in<strong>for</strong>mation<br />

There may be circumstances where the public sector has less in<strong>for</strong>mation than<br />

potential service providers, or some service providers possess less in<strong>for</strong>mation<br />

than others. Both of these cases can raise implementation issues.<br />

The first situation, which is related to incomplete contracts, arises when the<br />

public sector is not able to monitor the efficiency of the service provider. For<br />

example, if costs rise it may be difficult to know whether this is due to<br />

inefficiency on the part of the service provider or factors outside its control. To<br />

address this problem it may be desirable to transfer risk to the service provider<br />

(through a fixed-fee contract, <strong>for</strong> example) in order to increase its incentives to<br />

minimise costs – although this approach could increase short-run costs and may<br />

48

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!