14.12.2012 Views

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Public</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: <strong>Using</strong> <strong>Market</strong>-<strong>Based</strong> <strong>Approaches</strong><br />

Incentives to over-consume<br />

Whilst rationing the availability of a public good or service can lead to problems<br />

of cream skimming and customer dissatisfaction, not rationing availability may<br />

also generate unfavourable outcomes. This will be the case when introducing<br />

choice creates incentives <strong>for</strong> individuals to consume more of the good or service<br />

than would be socially optimal. Some schemes have natural limits that can be<br />

applied to prevent this without restricting effective choice, <strong>for</strong> example allowing<br />

a child to be enrolled in a maximum of one school at any one point in time. In<br />

schemes where citizens can exercise choice over how much of a good or service<br />

they consume, however, this balance may be more difficult to strike.<br />

CONCLUSION<br />

Introducing user choice to public services can lead to improved efficiency, a<br />

more customer-responsive service, and confer a sense of empowerment on<br />

consumers. However, it can also have adverse consequences in terms of<br />

inequality and segregation, and outcomes may suffer if there are in<strong>for</strong>mational<br />

failures. Our case study on choice-based lettings evaluates the evidence on all of<br />

these issues, and looks at how user choice has been successful in the area of<br />

social rented housing despite binding capacity constraints.<br />

<strong>Market</strong>able permits<br />

<strong>Market</strong>able permits have been used in the environmental sector as a means of<br />

controlling pollution. In this system the total amount of pollution allowed is<br />

‘capped’ and property rights are assigned to would-be polluters.<br />

The theory behind marketable permits stems from Coase’s intuition that<br />

problems caused by externalities can be resolved, without government<br />

intervention, if there are no transaction costs. 41 Coase noted that there is always<br />

someone who benefits and someone who loses from any given externality. For<br />

example, a factory that pollutes a river may damage the livelihood of farmers<br />

living downstream. If the property rights of the factory and farmers are welldefined<br />

then the externality can be addressed by a transaction between them. For<br />

example, if the farmers have a right to clean water then the factory owner buys<br />

from the farmers a right to pollute (which is rational provided the benefit to the<br />

factory exceeds the cost to the farmers). Conversely, if the factory owns a right to<br />

pollute the farmers can pay it to stop polluting (which is rational in the opposite<br />

case where the cost of pollution to the farmers exceeds the benefit to the factory).<br />

41 Coase, R. (1960)’ The problem of social costs’, The Journal of Law and Economics 3.<br />

56

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!