14.12.2012 Views

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

Public Policy: Using Market-Based Approaches - Department for ...

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Public</strong> <strong>Policy</strong>: <strong>Using</strong> <strong>Market</strong>-<strong>Based</strong> <strong>Approaches</strong><br />

attempt to achieve the same outcome; 12 or they could sell the right to become<br />

the monopolist and capture any monopoly profits <strong>for</strong> the public purse. 13<br />

PUBLIC GOODS<br />

<strong>Public</strong> goods have two characteristics which differentiate them from other goods<br />

and services: non-rivalry and non-excludability.<br />

● Non-rival goods or services have a zero marginal cost: the cost of supplying<br />

the good or service does not increase when the number of consumers or the<br />

volume of output they consume increases. An example of a non-rival good is<br />

a terrestrially broadcast television or radio service.<br />

● Non-excludable goods are goods or services where it is not possible to limit<br />

the number of consumers. In particular, suppliers are not able to provide<br />

services only to those who pay <strong>for</strong> them: other consumers can ‘free-ride’<br />

using the same service even though they have not paid to receive it.<br />

Examples of non-excludable goods include national defence and street<br />

lighting.<br />

A good which is both non-rival and non-excludable might not be provided by the<br />

private sector, or might be provided at a lower quantity than would maximise<br />

social welfare. If the supplier cannot exclude free-riders there is no incentive <strong>for</strong><br />

consumers to pay <strong>for</strong> the service, so the supplier might not be able to earn<br />

sufficient revenues to cover its costs, even when society would value its<br />

provision. The public sector may there<strong>for</strong>e need to intervene to ensure that such<br />

goods and services are provided in sufficient quantities.<br />

EXTERNALITIES<br />

The consumption of a good or service by one set of individuals can in some<br />

circumstances affect the welfare of others. This effect is called an externality.<br />

Externalities can be positive or negative. An example of a negative externality is<br />

the pollution created from the use of fossil fuels; an example of a positive<br />

externality is the benefit that a homeowner with a carefully tended garden<br />

confers on his neighbours. 14<br />

In the presence of an externality, the welfare society gains from the consumption<br />

of a product is different (higher or lower) than the welfare received by the<br />

suppliers and direct consumers of the product. As a result, the amount that<br />

direct consumers chose to use will not be the same as the level of consumption<br />

12 For a useful introduction to the issues of regulating natural monopolies see Armstrong, M., S. Cowan and J.<br />

Vickers. (1999) Regulatory Re<strong>for</strong>m: Economic Analysis and British Experience, The MIT Press: Cambridge, MA;<br />

and Newbery, D. (1999) Privatisation, Restructuring and Regulation of Network Industries, The MIT Press:<br />

Cambridge, MA.<br />

13 See Demsetz, H. (1968) ‘Why Regulate Utilities?’, Journal of Law and Economics, <strong>for</strong> the first paper suggesting<br />

that competition <strong>for</strong> a market with natural monopoly characteristics could result in an efficient outcome.<br />

14 This concept is related to that of public goods in that non-excludable public goods (e.g. street lighting and<br />

policing) create positive externalities.<br />

36

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!