13.07.2015 Views

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

168 Steven Horwitzmoney is be<strong>in</strong>g held somewhere by someone, that does not mean that the supply<strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for money are always <strong>in</strong> equilibrium with respect to each other. 4 Todraw that conclusion is to confuse the “desired” <strong>and</strong> the “actual,” or <strong>in</strong> the terms <strong>of</strong>the Swedish economists <strong>of</strong> the 1930s, it confuses the “ex ante” <strong>and</strong> the “ex post.”Just as with any other good where the amount purchased has to equal the amountsold, so too with money someone must be hold<strong>in</strong>g every dollar. However, that neednot mean people wish to hold those dollars, <strong>in</strong> the same way that goods markets <strong>in</strong>disequilibrium can mean frustrated potential buyers <strong>and</strong> sellers. Differences among<strong>in</strong>dividuals’ actual <strong>and</strong> desired hold<strong>in</strong>gs <strong>of</strong> money are proximal causes <strong>of</strong> themaffect<strong>in</strong>g the level <strong>of</strong> spend<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> the macroeconomy, as we shall see below. Whenthe supply <strong>of</strong> money is too large or too small, i.e., when we have <strong>in</strong>flation ordeflation, these discrepencies between actual <strong>and</strong> desired money balances appeareconomy-wide. The results are the various costs <strong>and</strong> discoord<strong>in</strong>ation associatedwith both <strong>in</strong>flation <strong>and</strong> deflation. To see those problems more completely, we needto turn to the third property noted above.<strong>Yeager</strong>’s (1968: 645) third property, the “rout<strong>in</strong>eness” <strong>of</strong> our acquisition <strong>of</strong>money, is one that has had less attention paid to it by Austrians historically, despiteit be<strong>in</strong>g at least as important as the other two for underst<strong>and</strong><strong>in</strong>g the monetaryeconomy. What <strong>Yeager</strong> argues is that we will always accept money <strong>in</strong> exchangeeven if this means temporarily hav<strong>in</strong>g more <strong>of</strong> it than we might wish to hold. Weknow we can always trade the excess for goods <strong>and</strong> services. The importantimplication <strong>of</strong> this <strong>in</strong>sight is that we have much more control over gett<strong>in</strong>g rid <strong>of</strong>money than we do obta<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g it. This po<strong>in</strong>t is particularly important when money is<strong>in</strong> short supply. If one’s money balances are lower than one would wish, one hasonly two basic options: acquire more money, or reduce one’s expenditures. Giventhat money cont<strong>in</strong>ues to arrive <strong>in</strong> a rout<strong>in</strong>e way, by reduc<strong>in</strong>g one’s expenditures,one can allow one’s money balances to replenish. Balances can also be replenishedby <strong>in</strong>creas<strong>in</strong>g one’s <strong>in</strong>come or by sell<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong>f assets, but both <strong>of</strong> those require thecooperation <strong>of</strong> will<strong>in</strong>g others. Reductions <strong>in</strong> expenditures are completely <strong>in</strong> thecontrol <strong>of</strong> the actor. With excess supplies <strong>of</strong> money, it certa<strong>in</strong>ly makes more sense toelim<strong>in</strong>ate the imbalance by spend<strong>in</strong>g it <strong>and</strong> acquir<strong>in</strong>g non-money assets than itwould to reduce one’s money hold<strong>in</strong>gs by reduc<strong>in</strong>g one’s <strong>in</strong>come!What becomes clear from <strong>Yeager</strong>’s approach is that discrepancies between theactual <strong>and</strong> desired quantity <strong>of</strong> money will result <strong>in</strong> changes <strong>in</strong> expenditures,affect<strong>in</strong>g the traditional macroeconomic aggregates. When actual hold<strong>in</strong>gs are lessthan desired hold<strong>in</strong>gs, expenditures will fall <strong>and</strong> recession will ensue <strong>in</strong> a process tobe explored below. When actual hold<strong>in</strong>gs exceed desired hold<strong>in</strong>gs, the excesses willbe spent, driv<strong>in</strong>g up prices <strong>and</strong> caus<strong>in</strong>g various forms <strong>of</strong> economic discoord<strong>in</strong>ationthat will also be explored below. The key po<strong>in</strong>t for reconcil<strong>in</strong>g <strong>Yeager</strong>’s approachwith that <strong>of</strong> the Austrians is to recognize that the former case, that <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>sufficientsupply, corresponds to the traditional monetary disequilibrium theory explanation<strong>of</strong> depressions, while the latter case, that <strong>of</strong> the excess supply, corresponds to theAustrian concern with <strong>in</strong>flation <strong>and</strong> the possibility that it could generate a bus<strong>in</strong>esscycle <strong>and</strong> eventual depression. These two theoretical approaches can fruitfully beseen as two elements <strong>of</strong> the same underly<strong>in</strong>g story.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!