13.07.2015 Views

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

204 Roger W. Garrison[Prices <strong>and</strong> Production (1931b), <strong>in</strong> which the <strong>in</strong>tertemporal structure <strong>of</strong> productionloomed large] marked the start <strong>of</strong> the neo-Ricardian counter-revolution. . . . Theaim <strong>of</strong> [this] counter-revolution is to undo the subjectivist revolution <strong>in</strong> economicthought which took place <strong>in</strong> the 1870s, led by Jevons, Menger <strong>and</strong> Walras.” Animportant difference between Sraffa (1932) <strong>and</strong> Cohen <strong>and</strong> Harcourt (2003a) isthat Sraffa <strong>of</strong>fered up his critical remarks while disguis<strong>in</strong>g his own preference forthe Ricardian way <strong>of</strong> th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g, which had fallen <strong>in</strong>to disfavor many decades earlier.Lachmann (1986: 228) expla<strong>in</strong>s: “The reason for the disguise he chose to wear isobvious. . . . The neo-Ricardian counter-revolution, <strong>in</strong> the circumstances <strong>of</strong> 1932,could not be expected to w<strong>in</strong> adherents. . . . For his polemical purpose it was betterthat [his readers] should be puzzled than that they might become suspicious.”If the 1932 Sraffa article can be seen as mark<strong>in</strong>g the start <strong>of</strong> the neo-Ricardianrevolution, we might wonder if <strong>in</strong> years to come the 2003 Cohen–Harcourt articlewill be seen as mark<strong>in</strong>g the end <strong>of</strong> it. The lack <strong>of</strong> a substantive answer to the“Whatever Happened?” question <strong>and</strong> the lack <strong>of</strong> appeal <strong>of</strong> the Ricardo–Sraffa way<strong>of</strong> th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g may give just such a special significance to 2003.The thrust <strong>of</strong> the present paper is that the alternative framework that Sraffa hid<strong>and</strong> that Cohen <strong>and</strong> Harcourt proudly advertise is a false one. We need not choosebetween Ricardo’s classical framework <strong>and</strong> some neoclassical-cum-Austrian framework.This overly constra<strong>in</strong>ed two-way choice becomes a three-way choice oncewe recognize that each <strong>of</strong> the three schools here is sufficiently dist<strong>in</strong>ct <strong>in</strong> terms <strong>of</strong> theperceived nature <strong>of</strong> the rate <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest <strong>and</strong> the role <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terest rate <strong>in</strong> achiev<strong>in</strong>ga coord<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> consumer preferences <strong>and</strong> production activities.The neoclassical school allows for a market determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terest rate (theloanable-funds theory) but does not allow for changes <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terest rate to haveany significant effect <strong>of</strong> the <strong>in</strong>tertemporal structure <strong>of</strong> capital. Ricardian classicismallows for changes <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terest rate to affect the <strong>in</strong>tertemporal structure <strong>of</strong> capital– though only through a switch<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> techniques <strong>and</strong> possibly a subsequentreswitch<strong>in</strong>g – but treats the <strong>in</strong>terest rate itself as if it were determ<strong>in</strong>ed outside theframework <strong>of</strong> analysis. The Austrian theory allows for a market determ<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>of</strong>the <strong>in</strong>terest rate <strong>and</strong> allows for changes <strong>in</strong> the <strong>in</strong>terest rate to govern the <strong>in</strong>tertemporalallocation <strong>of</strong> resources with<strong>in</strong> the economy’s capital structure. In fact,these two features are actually two perspectives on a s<strong>in</strong>gle feature. Intertemporalexchanges <strong>in</strong> the marketplace – whether directly registered <strong>in</strong> the market forloanable funds or <strong>in</strong>directly registered as a change <strong>in</strong> the price <strong>of</strong> early-stagecapital relative to late-stage capital – work to coord<strong>in</strong>ate the production decisions<strong>in</strong> the various temporally def<strong>in</strong>ed stages with <strong>in</strong>tertemporal consumption preferences.We can reject the idea that writ<strong>in</strong>g Q = f (K, L) somehow allows us to ignore thecomposition <strong>of</strong> the capital structure. Further, with ample support from Lel<strong>and</strong><strong>Yeager</strong>, we can reject the claim that the <strong>in</strong>tertemporal structure <strong>of</strong> capital must bespecified <strong>in</strong> physical terms <strong>and</strong> not value terms. Technique reswitch<strong>in</strong>g, a possibilitythat h<strong>in</strong>ges critically on a physical measure <strong>of</strong> capital, has little claim on ourattention. And the <strong>in</strong>sight that a change <strong>in</strong> the degree <strong>of</strong> roundaboutness, broughtabout by a change <strong>in</strong> sav<strong>in</strong>g <strong>and</strong> reckoned <strong>in</strong> value terms as the movements <strong>of</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!