13.07.2015 Views

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Ethnic conflict <strong>and</strong> the economics <strong>of</strong> social cooperation 225<strong>of</strong>ten used to refer to an aggregation <strong>of</strong> persons <strong>of</strong> the same ethnic family or race.This type <strong>of</strong> nation can be conf<strong>in</strong>ed to one region <strong>of</strong> the world or spread out overmany regions comm<strong>in</strong>gl<strong>in</strong>g with several other “nations.”The historian E.J. Hobsbawm argues that throughout the seventeenth,eighteenth, <strong>and</strong> most <strong>of</strong> the n<strong>in</strong>eteenth century it was the adm<strong>in</strong>istrative mean<strong>in</strong>g<strong>of</strong> nation-state – the one connected with territory <strong>and</strong> adm<strong>in</strong>istration – that wasused by the lead<strong>in</strong>g writers.The other notion <strong>of</strong> “nation,” the one l<strong>in</strong>ked to ancestry <strong>and</strong> common descent,has only recently come to dom<strong>in</strong>ate discussion <strong>in</strong> the social sciences. Until quiterecently, it was believed that “small, <strong>and</strong> especially small <strong>and</strong> backward,nationalities had everyth<strong>in</strong>g to ga<strong>in</strong> by merg<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong>to greater nations, <strong>and</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>gtheir contributions to humanity through these” (Hobsbawm 1990: 34). Nationsthat emphasized “dist<strong>in</strong>ctions <strong>of</strong> birth” tended to be poor <strong>and</strong> rema<strong>in</strong> poor. TheIndian caste system may be an important causal factor <strong>in</strong> the perpetuation <strong>of</strong>Indian poverty on the subcont<strong>in</strong>ent, for example (Van Den Berg 2001: 60–1).Smith expla<strong>in</strong>ed that “there are no nations among whom wealth is likely tocont<strong>in</strong>ue longer <strong>in</strong> the same families,” suggest<strong>in</strong>g that the redistribution <strong>of</strong> wealth isquite common with the pass<strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> time (Smith 1976 [1776]: 714). Smith arguedthat national prosperity depended on the skill <strong>of</strong> its workforce, which itselfdepended upon both the extent to which the division <strong>of</strong> labor had been extended<strong>and</strong> the success <strong>of</strong> those efforts to repeal or defeat special-<strong>in</strong>terest legislation. Smithsaw the “system <strong>of</strong> natural liberty” as a means <strong>of</strong> provid<strong>in</strong>g potentially immensebenefits to all men <strong>and</strong> women, regardless <strong>of</strong> ethnic orig<strong>in</strong>, race, or status at birth.This liberal idea <strong>of</strong> universal rules that would benefit all people regardless <strong>of</strong> anytribal, racial, or especially ethnic roots has its orig<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> Greek Stoic thought <strong>and</strong>,later, Christian doctr<strong>in</strong>e. The idea entered economics by way <strong>of</strong> the Salamancaneconomists <strong>and</strong>, after them, through the natural-law Protestant th<strong>in</strong>kers (Rothbard1995). Cosmopolitan th<strong>in</strong>k<strong>in</strong>g still dom<strong>in</strong>ates among lead<strong>in</strong>g social scientists.Surely this was Hayek’s view as it was the view <strong>of</strong> his mentor, Ludwig von Mises(Mises 1960 [1949]).2 Nationalism <strong>in</strong> the modern senseUntil the past century, nation-states were identified with territories generat<strong>in</strong>gannual production, possess<strong>in</strong>g a uniform currency, <strong>and</strong> conduct<strong>in</strong>g a coherent<strong>in</strong>ternational economic policy embrac<strong>in</strong>g tariffs, subsidies, <strong>and</strong> treaties. In mucheconomic theory, that sense <strong>of</strong> the word “nationalism” still holds. Accord<strong>in</strong>g toWalker Connor, “the <strong>in</strong>terutilization <strong>of</strong> nation <strong>and</strong> state [is a] careless use <strong>of</strong> term<strong>in</strong>ology.”It may be better to separate the two ideas <strong>and</strong> rename whole subject areasby remov<strong>in</strong>g the word “<strong>in</strong>ternational” <strong>and</strong> replac<strong>in</strong>g it with the word “<strong>in</strong>terstate.”Connor goes on to argue that terms like “national <strong>in</strong>come, national wealth, national<strong>in</strong>terest, <strong>and</strong> the like, refer <strong>in</strong> fact to statal concerns” (Connor 1994 [1978]: 40).Modern welfare economics assigns measures to “national welfare” <strong>and</strong> theorizesabout the causal mechanisms that exp<strong>and</strong> or retard those measures. It is difficult torecall any theoretical schema <strong>in</strong> the vast literature <strong>of</strong> what is termed “welfare

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!