13.07.2015 Views

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

228 Laurence S. MossThis table requires some additional explanation. When C-types trade with eachother, they produce the results that are discussed <strong>in</strong> nearly every textbook on economics.Their mutual ga<strong>in</strong> is derived from the process <strong>of</strong> specialization <strong>and</strong> exchange<strong>in</strong> accordance with comparative advantage. These ga<strong>in</strong>s are real <strong>and</strong> constitute thecore <strong>of</strong> orthodox economic analysis (<strong>Yeager</strong> 2001: 6). In the case <strong>of</strong> bilateralmonopoly, they split the ga<strong>in</strong>s <strong>in</strong> accordance with their relative barga<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g power.There is noth<strong>in</strong>g peculiar or unusual about this result <strong>in</strong> our model: It is st<strong>and</strong>ardeconomic analysis. It is the <strong>in</strong>troduction <strong>of</strong> the D-types that presents the problem.They encumber trade with opportunism, false promises, deception, <strong>and</strong> constantself-deal<strong>in</strong>g to the po<strong>in</strong>t where the C-types always come to regret that they tradedwith them <strong>in</strong> the first place. The C-types lose <strong>in</strong> two different ways. First, they knowthey would have done better trad<strong>in</strong>g with other C-types, <strong>and</strong> so they have <strong>in</strong>curredan opportunity cost by trad<strong>in</strong>g with the D-type. Second, they once <strong>in</strong> a while regretthe exchange when a D-type successfully completes a scam or fraud <strong>and</strong> their utilityga<strong>in</strong> turns negative! When a D-type trades with another D-type, they stir up somuch distrust <strong>and</strong> make so many dem<strong>and</strong>s for repeated authentication <strong>of</strong> everyrepresentation each makes to the other that the ga<strong>in</strong>s from trade are dissipatedamong lawyers, accountants, <strong>and</strong> various experts. Somehow the D-types net, onthe average, 10 utils each trade, but how much better could a D-type have done iftrad<strong>in</strong>g with a C-type!The D-type is not discussed <strong>in</strong> the orthodox economics literature, although <strong>in</strong>recent years the trend <strong>in</strong> certa<strong>in</strong> subfields <strong>of</strong> economics has been to devote sometime <strong>and</strong> attention to opportunistic behavior (Williamson 1975). Outside <strong>of</strong> thesesubfields <strong>and</strong> specialties, it is common <strong>in</strong> the textbook literature to assume that alleconomiz<strong>in</strong>g agents are honest <strong>in</strong> the sense that they are committed to liv<strong>in</strong>g with<strong>in</strong>their (notional) budget constra<strong>in</strong>ts <strong>and</strong>/or that <strong>in</strong>formation is freely available to all<strong>and</strong> that problems <strong>of</strong> asymmetric <strong>in</strong>formation <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>tentional misrepresentation are“exceptions” or m<strong>in</strong>or aberrations <strong>in</strong> market sett<strong>in</strong>gs (Leijonhufvud 1981). In ourmodel <strong>of</strong> C-types <strong>and</strong> D-types, we depart from the benign self-<strong>in</strong>terest approach toa more descriptively realistic approach that allows the opportunistic agent full re<strong>in</strong>to antagonize the economic welfare <strong>of</strong> the rest <strong>of</strong> society.Let us now follow Robert Frank, who suggested a dynamic pr<strong>in</strong>ciple <strong>of</strong> evolutionthat might illum<strong>in</strong>ate how the composition <strong>of</strong> the population <strong>in</strong> a region changesover time (Frank 1988: 56–65). Suppose that changes <strong>in</strong> the ratio <strong>of</strong> D-types to C-types <strong>in</strong> the population – what I shall call the “ethical composition” <strong>of</strong> thepopulation – depends on the relative pay<strong>of</strong>fs accru<strong>in</strong>g to the D-types. When theD-types do better on average than the C-types, they multiply more quickly. Thecomposition <strong>of</strong> the population then shifts <strong>in</strong> favor <strong>of</strong> the D-types (the D/C ratiorises), mak<strong>in</strong>g it more likely that a trader will encounter a D-type on his next trade. 7When the C-types do better than the D-types, then they procreate more rapidly <strong>and</strong>the D/C ratio falls.From the pay<strong>of</strong>fs presented <strong>in</strong> the table, it is immediately obvious that a C-typewould avoid trad<strong>in</strong>g with a D-type if he could costlessly “see one com<strong>in</strong>g.” 8 If thatwere the case, then we would have D-types trad<strong>in</strong>g only with other D-types, <strong>and</strong> thecomposition <strong>of</strong> the population would steadily shift <strong>in</strong> favor <strong>of</strong> the C-types, who ga<strong>in</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!