13.07.2015 Views

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

Money and Markets: Essays in Honor of Leland B. Yeager

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Monetary disequilibrium theory <strong>and</strong> Austrian macroeconomics 175as the direct “price <strong>of</strong> time.” Because we cannot exchange time directly, f<strong>in</strong>ancial<strong>in</strong>termediaries such as banks have evolved to trade time <strong>in</strong> the form <strong>of</strong> money. Thesupply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong> for loanable funds correspond, respectively, to a desire to partwith time by push<strong>in</strong>g consumption to the future <strong>and</strong> a desire to acquire time bypush<strong>in</strong>g consumption <strong>in</strong>to the present. To the extent that the supply <strong>and</strong> dem<strong>and</strong>for loanable funds is constituted only by the voluntary decisions <strong>of</strong> market actors, itis an accurate reflection <strong>of</strong> their underly<strong>in</strong>g preferences about time. Therefore, the<strong>in</strong>terest rate charged on loanable funds transactions (the market rate <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest) willbe an accurate reflection <strong>of</strong> the natural rate <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest.When monetary disequilibrium occurs, this analysis suggests that <strong>in</strong>tertemporaldiscoord<strong>in</strong>ation will follow. Should the money supply exp<strong>and</strong> beyond the dem<strong>and</strong>for real balances, the funds available for <strong>in</strong>vestment (the supply <strong>of</strong> bank liabilities)will exceed the sav<strong>in</strong>gs supplied by bank liability holders. The excess supply <strong>of</strong>money will drive market rates <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>terest down (ceteris paribus <strong>and</strong> start<strong>in</strong>g fromequilibrium) <strong>in</strong> order to pull <strong>in</strong> new borrowers, but by hypothesis, time preferenceshave not changed. With the market rate below the natural rate, we have the usualAustrian cycle theory story where the false signal transmitted by the market rateleads to mal<strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> the form <strong>of</strong> too many resources devoted to goods fartherfrom f<strong>in</strong>al consumption than is justified by the unchanged time preferences <strong>of</strong> thepublic. The public is not more will<strong>in</strong>g to part with time, but the artificially lowmarket rates suggest, falsely, that they are. In contrast to the 100 percent reservetheorists, the problem here is not the expansion <strong>of</strong> the money supply per se, but itbe<strong>in</strong>g <strong>in</strong> excess <strong>of</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> to hold real balances. For the <strong>Yeager</strong>-<strong>in</strong>fusedAustrian theory, the cycle can conceivably be triggered by a fall <strong>in</strong> the dem<strong>and</strong> formoney that is not met with a decl<strong>in</strong>e <strong>in</strong> the nom<strong>in</strong>al money supply.In two previous contributions (2000, 2002), I have argued that Austrian macroeconomicsis not only its theory <strong>of</strong> the bus<strong>in</strong>ess cycle, <strong>and</strong> that it has more to sayabout <strong>in</strong>flation than the cycle story. Central to those arguments is the idea that theeffects <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>flation are dispersed <strong>and</strong> uneven precisely because money has nomarket <strong>of</strong> its own <strong>and</strong> the excess supplies <strong>of</strong> money will therefore affect each <strong>and</strong>every market that the excess supply comes <strong>in</strong>to contact with. This core <strong>in</strong>sight comesfrom <strong>Yeager</strong> as does the underly<strong>in</strong>g cash balance approach to the dem<strong>and</strong> formoney. The result <strong>of</strong> this process is that the entire array <strong>of</strong> market prices is changed<strong>in</strong> unpredictable <strong>and</strong> vary<strong>in</strong>g ways by <strong>in</strong>flation. This creates additional epistemicburdens for entrepreneurs as they must attempt to disentangle the effects <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>flationfrom underly<strong>in</strong>g real changes. To the extent they err (<strong>and</strong> given the complexities<strong>of</strong> the market that will be frequently), resources get misallocated <strong>and</strong> distortionsresult. Inflation underm<strong>in</strong>es the process <strong>of</strong> economic calculation that Austrians seeas a partner with entrepreneurship <strong>in</strong> mak<strong>in</strong>g economic coord<strong>in</strong>ation <strong>and</strong> growthpossible. Specifically, to the extent economic miscalculation because <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>flationleads to <strong>in</strong>creased <strong>in</strong>vestment <strong>in</strong> fairly specific capital, the wastes <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>flation may belarge. More generally, this underm<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>g <strong>of</strong> the price system causes a lack <strong>of</strong> confidence<strong>in</strong> markets as <strong>in</strong>stitutions, <strong>and</strong> a preference, on the marg<strong>in</strong>, for <strong>in</strong>creased<strong>in</strong>tervention. All <strong>of</strong> these Austrian observations beg<strong>in</strong> with the <strong>Yeager</strong>ian <strong>in</strong>sightthat money is half <strong>of</strong> every exchange <strong>and</strong> that all markets are money markets.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!