01.06.2013 Views

Equality, Participation, Transition: Essays in Honour of Branko Horvat

Equality, Participation, Transition: Essays in Honour of Branko Horvat

Equality, Participation, Transition: Essays in Honour of Branko Horvat

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

74 Determ<strong>in</strong>ants <strong>of</strong> Income Inequality<br />

hypothesis), and may be thought to reflect actual <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality<br />

between <strong>in</strong>dividuals better than other <strong>in</strong>come concepts: for example, gross<br />

<strong>in</strong>come does not <strong>in</strong>clude direct personal taxes, while f<strong>in</strong>al <strong>in</strong>come adjusts,<br />

<strong>in</strong> an <strong>of</strong>ten arbitrary fashion, disposable <strong>in</strong>come for consumption <strong>of</strong> government<br />

<strong>in</strong>-k<strong>in</strong>d benefits (education and health).<br />

08 In some cases, gross <strong>in</strong>come is used when personal <strong>in</strong>come taxes are small,<br />

and disposable and gross <strong>in</strong>come are virtually the same.<br />

09 The po<strong>in</strong>t was raised by a referee.<br />

10 This expla<strong>in</strong>s why equivalence scales vary between the countries and why<br />

there cannot be equivalence scales <strong>in</strong>dependent <strong>of</strong> specific country conditions.<br />

The ‘correct’ scale for a country is a function <strong>of</strong> the country’s relative<br />

price ratios. Consider the example <strong>of</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g, assum<strong>in</strong>g, for simplicity, that<br />

a family needs to pay only for hous<strong>in</strong>g and food. Suppose that food costs<br />

are proportional to the number <strong>of</strong> people, while hous<strong>in</strong>g is not. For the same<br />

level <strong>of</strong> hous<strong>in</strong>g comfort, a s<strong>in</strong>gle person <strong>in</strong> the US might need $800 per<br />

month, and a five-member family $2000. This implies that a five-member<br />

household should be (for the hous<strong>in</strong>g purposes) treated as 2½ adults. Food<br />

costs for each household member are, say $300. Then the household <strong>of</strong> five<br />

would require 5$300$2000$3500 to be equally well-<strong>of</strong>f as the household<br />

<strong>of</strong> one that has $1100 ($300 for food$800 for hous<strong>in</strong>g). The implicit<br />

equivalence scales is 3.18 (3500/1100). Now let hous<strong>in</strong>g costs become practically<br />

zero, as they were <strong>in</strong> the former socialist countries. Suppose that the<br />

costs are now $8 for a s<strong>in</strong>gle person and $20 for the family <strong>of</strong> five. While<br />

the economies <strong>of</strong> scale for the hous<strong>in</strong>g alone are the same, their overall<br />

importance is much less now simply because hous<strong>in</strong>g costs no longer matter<br />

very much. Thus, a s<strong>in</strong>gle person would now require $308 and the fivemember<br />

household 5$300$20$1520. The implicit equivalence scale is<br />

now 4.93 (1520 divided by 308), and we are practically <strong>in</strong> the world <strong>of</strong> per<br />

capita comparisons. This is exactly the reason why per capita measurement<br />

made quite a lot <strong>of</strong> sense <strong>in</strong> the former socialist countries.<br />

11 The expected negative sign <strong>of</strong> TRANS deserves a further comment. As has<br />

been argued, <strong>in</strong>creased social transfers will tend to reduce the <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>of</strong><br />

disposable or gross <strong>in</strong>come. But <strong>in</strong> some recent studies (for example, Ales<strong>in</strong>a<br />

and Rodrik, 1994; Persson and Tabell<strong>in</strong>i, 1992) which are concerned with<br />

determ<strong>in</strong>ants <strong>of</strong> social transfers, higher <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality is shown to lead,<br />

<strong>in</strong> conditions <strong>of</strong> wide franchise, to high redistribution. It would hence appear<br />

that <strong>in</strong>equality and transfers are positively related. The example underscores<br />

the ambiguity with which the term ‘<strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality’ is used. The positive<br />

relationship between <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality and transfers makes sense only if<br />

one has <strong>in</strong> m<strong>in</strong>d <strong>in</strong>equality <strong>of</strong> market <strong>in</strong>come (before government benefits<br />

and taxes). It is then logical to assume that if market <strong>in</strong>comes are distributed<br />

unequally, people (that is the median voter) will vote for large redistribution<br />

because they will thereby ga<strong>in</strong>. But both Ales<strong>in</strong>a and Rodrik (1994)<br />

and Persson and Tabell<strong>in</strong>i (1992) use measures <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality after<br />

government cash transfers. Consequently, the cross-country relationship<br />

between market <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality and TRANS may be positive (because<br />

taxes are higher <strong>in</strong> more unequal countries), while the cross-country relationship<br />

between TRANS and disposable or gross <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality may be<br />

negative (because transfers paid out <strong>of</strong> taxes lower <strong>in</strong>equality). The two

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!