01.06.2013 Views

Equality, Participation, Transition: Essays in Honour of Branko Horvat

Equality, Participation, Transition: Essays in Honour of Branko Horvat

Equality, Participation, Transition: Essays in Honour of Branko Horvat

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Branko</strong> Milanović 55<br />

ascend<strong>in</strong>g order accord<strong>in</strong>g to INCOME; each country has an equal<br />

weight.<br />

All the coefficients (see Table 4.2) have the predicted sign and are<br />

statistically significant at 1 per cent level. 12 The <strong>in</strong>tercept is not statistically<br />

significantly different from zero. This means that, for a sufficiently<br />

low per capita <strong>in</strong>come (at the limit for INCOME0) and <strong>in</strong> the absence<br />

<strong>of</strong> state sector employment and transfers, the G<strong>in</strong>i coefficient would be<br />

close to zero: that is, no <strong>in</strong>equality would exist. The adjusted coefficient<br />

<strong>of</strong> determ<strong>in</strong>ation is 0.70. 13 The <strong>in</strong>terpretation <strong>of</strong> the results is as follows.<br />

Each ten percentage po<strong>in</strong>t <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> the share <strong>of</strong> state-sector<br />

workers reduces <strong>in</strong>equality, on average, by 2.2 G<strong>in</strong>i po<strong>in</strong>ts; each<br />

<strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> social transfers by 10 GDP percentage po<strong>in</strong>ts lowers<br />

<strong>in</strong>equality by 4.15 G<strong>in</strong>i po<strong>in</strong>ts. The relationship between <strong>in</strong>come level<br />

and <strong>in</strong>equality is quadratic: at first, <strong>in</strong>equality rises with <strong>in</strong>come and<br />

then decl<strong>in</strong>es. The turn<strong>in</strong>g po<strong>in</strong>t is reached for $2100 per capita (at<br />

1988 <strong>in</strong>ternational prices) which is broadly the level <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come <strong>of</strong> the<br />

Philipp<strong>in</strong>es, Swaziland, or Sri Lanka. 14<br />

There is a heteroskedasticity problem with equation (1.0). It was<br />

observed <strong>in</strong> the literature (see L<strong>in</strong>dert and Williamson, 1985: 344;<br />

Lecaillon et al., 1984: 40) that the dispersion <strong>of</strong> the G<strong>in</strong>i is greater<br />

at low than at high <strong>in</strong>come levels. One can therefore expect some<br />

heteroskedasticity because standard errors would systematically decl<strong>in</strong>e<br />

with <strong>in</strong>crease <strong>in</strong> <strong>in</strong>come level. Indeed, this is exactly the case, as shown<br />

<strong>in</strong> Figure 4.2, where residuals from equation (1.0) are plotted aga<strong>in</strong>st<br />

<strong>in</strong>come levels. Regression (1) is the same as (1.0) except that I correct<br />

for heteroskedasticity by runn<strong>in</strong>g OLS with White’s heteroskedasticconsistent<br />

standard errors. 15 Values <strong>of</strong> the coefficients do not change.<br />

Significance <strong>of</strong> STATE or TRANS is also unaffected but the two <strong>in</strong>come<br />

terms become statistically significant at 5 per cent level rather than at 1<br />

per cent as <strong>in</strong> regression 1.0. S<strong>in</strong>ce the same problem exists <strong>in</strong> all equations,<br />

all regressions will henceforth be run with the correction for<br />

heteroskedasticity. I shall explore next whether these results are sufficiently<br />

robust to a different specification <strong>of</strong> each <strong>of</strong> the variables used<br />

here. I shall start with the dependent variable, a measure <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality.<br />

16 As expla<strong>in</strong>ed <strong>in</strong> the Annex, I have collected the <strong>in</strong>come G<strong>in</strong>i<br />

coefficients for 80 countries for the period <strong>of</strong> the 1980s with a specific<br />

purpose to use it for this study (I call it, for simplicity, even if somewhat<br />

self-serv<strong>in</strong>gly, the Milanović data set). 17 S<strong>in</strong>ce <strong>in</strong>equality measures<br />

are notoriously fickle, one can wonder if the same results would<br />

obta<strong>in</strong> with <strong>in</strong>equality measures com<strong>in</strong>g from a different source. To<br />

do this, I use the De<strong>in</strong><strong>in</strong>ger and Squire (1996) ‘high-quality’ data set

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!