01.06.2013 Views

Equality, Participation, Transition: Essays in Honour of Branko Horvat

Equality, Participation, Transition: Essays in Honour of Branko Horvat

Equality, Participation, Transition: Essays in Honour of Branko Horvat

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

76 Determ<strong>in</strong>ants <strong>of</strong> Income Inequality<br />

26 The only other one is Ghana.<br />

27 The data come from the United Nations Development Program (1992).<br />

28 Different formulations us<strong>in</strong>g INCOME and EDUC were tried; none dispenses<br />

with the need for a dummy variable.<br />

29 The ‘importance’ is measured by how much GINI is reduced ow<strong>in</strong>g to<br />

changes <strong>in</strong> STATE and TRANS at various levels <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come.<br />

30 At some, possibly mythical, extremely low level <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come, everyone would<br />

be equally poor. But this is not true at the actual low levels <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>come<br />

which we observe <strong>in</strong> our sample.<br />

31 Annex Table 3, as well as Annex Tables 1 and 2 (referred to later <strong>in</strong> the text)<br />

can be obta<strong>in</strong>ed from the author upon request.<br />

32 Consumer subsidies and nomenklatura <strong>in</strong>-k<strong>in</strong>d benefits are not <strong>in</strong>cluded <strong>in</strong><br />

<strong>in</strong>come. Includ<strong>in</strong>g an estimate <strong>of</strong> the latter would make <strong>in</strong>equality greater<br />

although not by a substantial amount. Us<strong>in</strong>g Matthews’s (1978) estimates<br />

for the Soviet Union, and his own estimates for Eastern Europe, Morrisson<br />

(1984) f<strong>in</strong>ds that <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g the monetized value <strong>of</strong> the nomenklatura benefits<br />

raises the G<strong>in</strong>i coefficient by 3 to 4 G<strong>in</strong>i po<strong>in</strong>ts (see Morrisson, 1984,<br />

Table 2). As for consumer subsidies, they are overall <strong>in</strong>come equalizers s<strong>in</strong>ce<br />

they were mostly concentrated on goods with low <strong>in</strong>come elasticity <strong>of</strong> consumption,<br />

like food. Two very careful studies that assessed the impact <strong>of</strong><br />

consumer subsidies <strong>in</strong> Poland (World Bank 1989) and Hungary (Kupa and<br />

Fajth 1990) f<strong>in</strong>d that they reduce <strong>in</strong>come <strong>in</strong>equality by about 2 G<strong>in</strong>i po<strong>in</strong>ts.<br />

Similar results were reported for Czechoslovakia (World Bank 1991). The<br />

studies cover all consumer subsidies, <strong>in</strong>clud<strong>in</strong>g those that are neutral or<br />

pro-rich, like hous<strong>in</strong>g, transportation or electricity subsidies. In conclusion,<br />

it seems that the <strong>in</strong>clusion <strong>of</strong> consumer subsidies on top <strong>of</strong> the nomenklatura<br />

perks would probably br<strong>in</strong>g the G<strong>in</strong>i coefficient close to its reported<br />

value. A more serious problem with <strong>in</strong>come distribution data from socialist<br />

countries exists <strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> the USSR, Bulgaria and Romania. The sampl<strong>in</strong>g<br />

procedure <strong>in</strong> these countries was biased because the selection was<br />

done, not at the place <strong>of</strong> residence, but at the work-place. The likelihood <strong>of</strong><br />

be<strong>in</strong>g selected was a function <strong>of</strong> employment status. There was, <strong>in</strong> addition,<br />

<strong>in</strong>formal pressure to select the 'average' households (both spouses work<strong>in</strong>g<br />

<strong>in</strong> the state sector, two children and so on) – a k<strong>in</strong>d <strong>of</strong> model ‘socialist’<br />

household. Pensioners, students, housewives, the unemployed, vagrants<br />

and so on were systematically undersampled. Although the surveys tries to<br />

correct for this by, for example, add<strong>in</strong>g on a quota <strong>of</strong> pensioners, their<br />

numbers were still relatively few. The procedure led to ‘averag<strong>in</strong>g out’ and<br />

thus an underestimate <strong>of</strong> <strong>in</strong>equality. However, this bias was much less or<br />

did not exist <strong>in</strong> other socialist countries, whose sampl<strong>in</strong>g procedures were<br />

comparable to those <strong>in</strong> the West (see Atk<strong>in</strong>son and Micklewright 1992, and<br />

Garner, Okrasa, Smeed<strong>in</strong>g and Boyle Torrey 1993).<br />

33 The dist<strong>in</strong>ction is, <strong>of</strong> course, somewhat artificial <strong>in</strong> the case <strong>of</strong> countries<br />

with agricultural underemployment.<br />

References<br />

Ahluwalia, M. S. (1976) ‘Inequality, Poverty and Development’, Journal <strong>of</strong><br />

Development Economics, no. 3.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!