19.11.2014 Views

Full Report - Subregional Office for East and North-East Asia - escap

Full Report - Subregional Office for East and North-East Asia - escap

Full Report - Subregional Office for East and North-East Asia - escap

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

DEVELOPMENTAL MACROECONOMICS: THE CRITICAL ROLE OF PUBLIC EXPENDITURE CHAPTER 3<br />

Box 3.2. (continued)<br />

observed that “historically, all possible combinations have occurred: inflation with <strong>and</strong> without [economic] development, no<br />

inflation with <strong>and</strong> without [economic] development” (p. 41 in his book).<br />

Similar is the case <strong>for</strong> the relationship between public debt <strong>and</strong> macroeconomic instability. The mild positive relationship is driven<br />

by outliers. In fact, there is no optimum debt-GDP ratio. A debt-to-GDP ratio of 60% is quite often noted as a prudential limit<br />

<strong>for</strong> developed countries, which suggests that crossing this limit will threaten fiscal sustainability. For developing <strong>and</strong> emerging<br />

economies, 40% is the suggested debt-to-GDP ratio that should not be breached on a long-term basis.<br />

The 60% figure was one of a h<strong>and</strong>ful of targets that European Governments set at the start of the 1990s to prepare <strong>for</strong> economic<br />

<strong>and</strong> monetary union <strong>and</strong> the eventual <strong>for</strong>mation of the euro zone. There was no hint of optimality: this level was simply the<br />

median debt-to-GDP ratio. Jonathan D. Ostry <strong>and</strong> others writing on “Fiscal space” in an IMF note (SPN/10/11, September 2010)<br />

emphasized that the debt limit found in their research “is not an absolute <strong>and</strong> immutable barrier .... Nor should the limit be<br />

interpreted as being the optimal level of public debt”. According to this IMF study by Ostry <strong>and</strong> others of 23 advanced countries,<br />

the estimated debt limits, using the historical interest-rate-growth-rate differential, ranged from about 150% to 260% of GDP,<br />

with the median being 192%. In the study it was assumed that interest-rate-growth-rate differentials were generally projected to<br />

be less favourable than the historical experience. It was found that the corresponding median long-run debt ratio was 63% of<br />

GDP <strong>and</strong> the median maximum debt ratio 183% of GDP.<br />

In the 2012 IMF publication, entitled World Economic Outlook: Coping with High Debt <strong>and</strong> Sluggish Growth, it is clearly<br />

acknowledged that debt thresholds are not robust: “(T)here is no simple relationship between debt <strong>and</strong> growth. In fact, our …<br />

analysis emphasizes that there are many factors that matter <strong>for</strong> a country’s growth <strong>and</strong> debt per<strong>for</strong>mance. Moreover, there is<br />

no single threshold <strong>for</strong> debt ratios that can delineate the ‘bad’ from the ‘good’.” (p. 109).<br />

However, there should be some distinction between domestic <strong>and</strong> external debts. Countries should be more cautious about<br />

external debts due to additional risk of exchange rate changes. In the IMF paper entitled “Assessing sustainability” (28 May<br />

2002), it is noted that “...an external debt ratio of about 40 percent provides a useful benchmark” (p. 25). In interpreting this<br />

benchmark, the authors of the report quickly added an important caveat: “… it bears emphasizing that a debt ratio above 40<br />

percent of GDP by no means necessarily implies a crisis – indeed, … there is an 80 percent probability of not having a crisis<br />

(even when the debt ratio exceeds 40 percent of GDP).”<br />

The above discussion does not provide a reason <strong>for</strong> deliberately creating high inflation or high debt or deficit through irresponsible<br />

macroeconomic policies. Instead, it highlights the need <strong>for</strong> achieving a balance between the stabilization <strong>and</strong> development roles<br />

of macroeconomic policies. Monetary expansion to support productive investment may not cause inflation in the long-run,<br />

<strong>and</strong> moderate inflation enhances fiscal space. The sustainability of a fiscal deficit itself depends on the productivity of public<br />

expenditure. An explicit focus on the composition of public expenditure <strong>and</strong> their growth effects would enable both stabilization<br />

<strong>and</strong> growth objectives to be addressed in more sustainable ways. There<strong>for</strong>e, there should be a fuller consideration of the growth<br />

effects of various kinds of government expenditure in designing fiscal policy.<br />

143

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!