19.11.2014 Views

Full Report - Subregional Office for East and North-East Asia - escap

Full Report - Subregional Office for East and North-East Asia - escap

Full Report - Subregional Office for East and North-East Asia - escap

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

ECONOMIC AND SOCIAL SURVEY OF ASIA AND THE PACIFIC 2013<br />

There<strong>for</strong>e, capital inflows are not costless; large<br />

capital flows can make macroeconomic management<br />

more difficult <strong>and</strong> the financial sector fragile. As<br />

the <strong>Asia</strong>n crisis has amply demonstrated, even<br />

countries at a higher level of development (often<br />

referred to as emerging market economies) found<br />

it difficult to h<strong>and</strong>le the uncertainty <strong>and</strong> volatility of<br />

short-term capital flows.<br />

The same experience is being repeated during the<br />

ongoing economic crisis in Europe <strong>and</strong> the United<br />

States. Private capital flows to emerging economies<br />

rebounded from their short-lived slump in the last<br />

quarter of 2008 <strong>and</strong> early 2009. Net private inflows<br />

to emerging economies are estimated to have been<br />

$825 billion in 2010, up from $581 billion in 2009.<br />

The prospects of relatively slow growth <strong>and</strong> low<br />

interest rates in advanced countries, rapid growth <strong>and</strong><br />

higher interest rates in emerging markets <strong>and</strong> reduced<br />

risk aversion suggest that private capital flows may<br />

continue to surge. This is putting upward pressure on<br />

exchange rates, denting export competitiveness <strong>and</strong><br />

threatening to stifle their economic recoveries. The<br />

surge is also <strong>for</strong>cing reserve accumulation, which, if<br />

left “unsterilized”, adds to inflationary pressures <strong>and</strong><br />

could trigger asset bubbles. Additionally, persistent<br />

vulnerabilities in advanced countries could trigger a<br />

new shock (<strong>for</strong> example, much higher policy rates,<br />

or even a recession) <strong>and</strong> trans<strong>for</strong>m the feast of<br />

capital flows into a famine, with serious destabilizing<br />

effects <strong>for</strong> receiving countries.<br />

In response, a number of countries, including Brazil,<br />

Indonesia, the Republic of Korea <strong>and</strong> Thail<strong>and</strong>,<br />

have introduced defensive measures against capital<br />

flows. India <strong>and</strong> the Republic of Korea may tighten<br />

their controls even further, while central banks<br />

in emerging market economies are very worried<br />

about “hot-money” flows. Similarly, during the<br />

1990s, policymakers in Chile, China, Colombia,<br />

India, Malaysia, Singapore <strong>and</strong> Taiwan Province of<br />

China used capital account management techniques<br />

to achieve crucial macroeconomic objectives.<br />

These included: preventing maturity <strong>and</strong> locational<br />

mismatches; attracting desired <strong>for</strong>eign investment;<br />

reducing overall financial fragility, currency risk<br />

<strong>and</strong> speculative pressures; insulating against the<br />

contagion effects of financial crises; <strong>and</strong> enhancing<br />

economic <strong>and</strong> social policy space.<br />

In support of their argument, critics of full capital<br />

account convertibility used the evidence of successful<br />

economies, such as Malaysia, the Republic of Korea<br />

<strong>and</strong> Taiwan Province of China, which had capital<br />

controls in place during the periods of their rapid<br />

trans<strong>for</strong>mation. In fact, it is now widely accepted<br />

that China, India <strong>and</strong> Viet Nam were able to<br />

avoid the contagion of the <strong>Asia</strong>n financial crisis<br />

due to controls on their capital account (Islam<br />

<strong>and</strong> Chowdhury, 2000). Most observers believe<br />

that Malaysia’s belated action to restrict capital<br />

mobility was the right step that helped it ride over<br />

the financial crisis of 1997-1998.<br />

From a developmental perspective,<br />

capital account openness should not<br />

be viewed as<br />

an all-or-nothing position<br />

Capital flows management is a sovereign right of<br />

a country under the IMF Articles of Agreement<br />

(Article VI). Owing to increased risks arising from<br />

volatile capital flows, IMF has recently designed<br />

capital flows management techniques. It notes: 28<br />

Rapid capital inflow surges or disruptive<br />

outflows can create policy challenges.<br />

Appropriate policy responses comprise a<br />

range of measures, <strong>and</strong> involve both countries<br />

that are recipients of capital flows <strong>and</strong> those<br />

from which flows originate. For countries<br />

that have to manage the macroeconomic<br />

<strong>and</strong> financial stability risks associated with<br />

inflow surges or disruptive outflows, a key<br />

role needs to be played by macroeconomic<br />

policies, including monetary, fiscal, <strong>and</strong><br />

exchange rate management, as well as by<br />

sound financial supervision <strong>and</strong> regulation <strong>and</strong><br />

strong institutions. In certain circumstances,<br />

capital flow management measures can be<br />

useful. They should not, however, substitute<br />

<strong>for</strong> warranted macroeconomic adjustment.<br />

156

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!