03.01.2015 Views

OPINION Vol.1, No.1 June 2013 - National Defence University

OPINION Vol.1, No.1 June 2013 - National Defence University

OPINION Vol.1, No.1 June 2013 - National Defence University

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

• Determine the punishment regime for non-compliance.<br />

• Determine inducements to encourage compliance.<br />

Step Two: Assessing the Environment. Situational-contextual factors can be exploited to ensure<br />

a flexible coercion strategy. There are no hard and fast rules for assessing the environment and it is<br />

dangerous to transfer ‘lessons’ from past coercive strategies if the environmental factors are even<br />

subtly different.<br />

Step Three: Select the Form of Coercion. Selecting a coercion form is important because it<br />

provides clarity of purpose. The factors affecting future coercion mean that opportunities to use<br />

George’s classic and tacit ultimatum successfully are diminishing, as they rely on the threat of<br />

harsh punishment with little tolerance for non-compliance. The try and see approach is also<br />

unlikely, as explained later. Therefore, the most likely of George’s forms in future coercion are<br />

incremental coercion and the limited threat. However, in the light of future coercion factors, some<br />

other forms have been added:-<br />

• Underdog Coercion. A weak state is able to threaten a stronger state if it has some<br />

hold over it. This may be an active hold, such as control of a vital commodity, or a<br />

passive hold, such as not taking action against internal militants threatening the stronger<br />

state. The weaker state takes advantage of the situation by refusing to cooperate unless<br />

the stronger state offers something in return. This coercion could be used as a countercoercive<br />

measure or as coercion in its own right.<br />

• Incentivized Coercion. This is where a mix of carrot and stick is used, similar to the<br />

limited threat, but the inducements are decided from the outset.<br />

• Baited Coercion. One state coerces another into something they are unlikely to<br />

cooperate on, by offering them the bait of something they want. The coercing state must<br />

‘oversell’ the ‘bait’, to make it sufficiently attractive, whilst minimizing the downstream<br />

risks, which may affect the coerced states’ national interests. An example is the core<br />

European States who pushed for greater integration by playing up the attractions of a<br />

unitary currency, so as to persuade satellite states to join the Euro zone. The downstream<br />

risks, such as stringent monetary policies and austerity packages, were deliberately<br />

undersold.<br />

Step Four: Opponent Evaluation. In this step, you assess the strengths and weaknesses of the<br />

target state, ensuring you anticipate likely reactions and responses from the opponent's perspective.<br />

This step is key and Pape’s Punishment theory (for rational opponents) or Engelbrecht’s 2 nd Order<br />

Theory (for irrational opponents) could be used to gauge the viability of Steps One to Three. If<br />

they were judged unviable, it would be prudent to return to step one and adjust the variables or to<br />

step three to change the form of coercion.<br />

The Application of Future Coercive Modalities<br />

Whichever modality is used, it will have to be considerably more sophisticated to succeed. A way<br />

to think through a strategy in detail is to ‘war game’ it, so that contingency plans are developed in<br />

anticipation of as many outcomes as possible. ‘War gaming’ is a military concept increasingly used in<br />

other spheres and increasingly relies on support tools. A tool for the analysis of strategic interaction,<br />

called Game Theory, gained a practical application when the US government financed research into its use<br />

for national security purposes in the mid-1960s, to find ways to outmanoeuvre the Soviet Union in the art<br />

of statecraft. In 1994, the Nobel Prize in Economics went to three game theorists, the mathematician John<br />

Nash, the economist Reinchard Selten, and the strategic theorist John Harsanyi. 32 Therefore, for future<br />

success, coercive statecraft will be less about threatening states with war and more about threatening them<br />

economically (through smart sanctions, such as finance). Although political concerns will continue, it will<br />

be more about ensuring resource security than territorial disputes. It will also be about the end state being<br />

cloaked by a more credible and proportionate intermediary state. Coercion is therefore likely to involve<br />

many steps (reciprocity, with clarity and over limited time). Additionally, coercive statecraft will be less<br />

about threatening to sponsor internal dissidents within a coerced state due to uncertain consequences and<br />

more about being coercive with allies, although there will be a balance between universal support and<br />

forming a narrower coalition with clearer goals and will. Also it will be more about ensuring the<br />

<strong>OPINION</strong> <strong>Vol.1</strong> <strong>No.1</strong> 29 <strong>June</strong> <strong>2013</strong>

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!