14.01.2013 Views

The Economics of Desertification, Land Degradation, and Drought

The Economics of Desertification, Land Degradation, and Drought

The Economics of Desertification, Land Degradation, and Drought

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

Figure 6.12—Cost <strong>of</strong> action <strong>and</strong> inaction (US$/ha) <strong>of</strong> soil erosion on maize plots in the Andean<br />

region, Peru<br />

Cost <strong>of</strong> action<br />

Cost <strong>of</strong> inaction<br />

Source: Posthumus <strong>and</strong> de Graaf (2005).<br />

Notes: Cost <strong>of</strong> action is the establishment cost <strong>of</strong> terraces, <strong>and</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> inaction is the loss <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>it (NPV calculated after<br />

netting the NPV that the farmer will get if he or she did establish terraces).<br />

<strong>The</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> salinity in Peru was also evaluated, using rice as a case study. Rice yield in Peru is<br />

among the highest in the world. For example, whereas the average paddy rice yield in India was 3.2<br />

tons per hectare for 2005–2009, it was more than twice that (7.15 tons per hectare) in Peru<br />

(FAOSTAT 2009). However, salinity has a large impact on rice yield. Crop simulation results showed<br />

that salinity reduced rice yield by 22 percent in Peru, which leads to a loss <strong>of</strong> $402 (Figure 6.13). As<br />

discussed earlier, salinity could be controlled by staggered leaching, an action that involves more use<br />

<strong>of</strong> water <strong>and</strong> labor for leaching. <strong>The</strong> cost <strong>of</strong> desalinization in Peru was $69 (Figure 6.13), which is<br />

only 17 percent <strong>of</strong> the cost <strong>of</strong> not taking action to control salinity.<br />

Figure 6.13—Cost <strong>of</strong> action <strong>and</strong> inaction to address salinity, India <strong>and</strong> Peru<br />

Cost (US$/ha)<br />

450<br />

400<br />

350<br />

300<br />

250<br />

200<br />

150<br />

100<br />

50<br />

0<br />

984<br />

108<br />

364<br />

Cost <strong>of</strong> action<br />

Cost <strong>of</strong> inaction<br />

176<br />

69<br />

India Peru<br />

Source: Authors’ calculations from simulation results.<br />

Notes: Cost <strong>of</strong> action includes water for leaching ($100 per hectare in India <strong>and</strong> $50 per hectare in Peru) <strong>and</strong> three-day labor<br />

costs for leaching ($6.25 per day in Peru <strong>and</strong> $2.25 per day in India).<br />

Success Stories <strong>of</strong> <strong>L<strong>and</strong></strong> Management in Peru<br />

Until only recently, Peru’s natural resource management had been highly centralized (Anderson <strong>and</strong><br />

Ostrom 2008), which meant that local communities did not have an opportunity to develop the<br />

capacity to locally manage natural resources. For example, the Peruvian government does not give<br />

m<strong>and</strong>ates for municipalities to formulate bylaws for natural resource management (NRM), nor does it<br />

permit municipalities to raise taxes or transfer funds for NRM (Anderson <strong>and</strong> Ostrom 2008). <strong>The</strong><br />

authors concluded that decentralization alone does not guarantee better NRM; rather local institutions<br />

109<br />

.<br />

402<br />

.

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!