14.01.2013 Views

The Economics of Desertification, Land Degradation, and Drought

The Economics of Desertification, Land Degradation, and Drought

The Economics of Desertification, Land Degradation, and Drought

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Figure 1.3—Prevention, mitigation, <strong>and</strong> rehabilitation costs over time<br />

Source: Schwilch et al. 2009.<br />

Note: SLM = sustainable l<strong>and</strong> management<br />

<strong>The</strong> choice <strong>of</strong> discount rates <strong>and</strong> time horizon is crucial, because the size <strong>of</strong> the discount rate,<br />

as well as the length <strong>of</strong> the considered time horizon, can radically change the results. Discount rates<br />

relate to people’s time preference, with higher discount rates indicating a strong time preference <strong>and</strong><br />

attaching a higher value to each unit <strong>of</strong> the natural resource that is consumed now rather than in the<br />

future. Assume a future benefit <strong>of</strong> sustainable l<strong>and</strong> management <strong>of</strong> $10,000. If the discount rate were<br />

3 percent, then the present value <strong>of</strong> the benefit <strong>of</strong> $10,000 earned in 10 years from now would only be<br />

$7.441. A zero discount rate refers to no time preference at all <strong>and</strong> the equal valuation <strong>of</strong> a unit <strong>of</strong> the<br />

resource consumed in the present or in the future. High discount rates, therefore, tend to discourage<br />

investments that generate long-term benefits <strong>and</strong> favor those that create short-term benefits but<br />

significant long-term costs. <strong>The</strong> social discount rate, from the perspective <strong>of</strong> society as a whole, is<br />

usually much lower than the discount rate <strong>of</strong> individuals; from a societal point <strong>of</strong> view, the value <strong>of</strong> a<br />

unit <strong>of</strong> the natural resource consumed by this generation or the next is the same, everything else being<br />

kept constant, whereas this does not hold from an individual’s perspective. Further, discount rates can<br />

actually differ across individuals, based on socioeconomic factors, attitude toward risk, <strong>and</strong><br />

uncertainty. When applying the methodology presented in this report, the issue <strong>of</strong> discounting <strong>and</strong><br />

time <strong>and</strong> planning horizons needs to be clearly elaborated. What discount rate to set is primarily an<br />

ethical question. Following the argument that present generations have the moral obligation to protect<br />

the interests <strong>of</strong> future generations would lead to rather low discount rates. Actions <strong>of</strong> today’s<br />

generation impose intergenerational externalities, such as loss <strong>of</strong> biodiversity, on future generations.<br />

On the other h<strong>and</strong>, today’s investments are likely to increase the wealth <strong>of</strong> future generations, which<br />

allows them to more easily address environmental protection, at least as long as environmental<br />

damage is reversible. <strong>The</strong> existence <strong>of</strong> inflation, time preference, <strong>and</strong> the opportunity cost <strong>of</strong> capital<br />

suggests that a positive discount rate better reflects societal preferences. Similar to Stern (2006), we<br />

propose using a low discount rate (around the 0.5 percent mark) for the economic assessment <strong>of</strong><br />

DLDD. This kind <strong>of</strong> value is particularly motivated by the long-term nature <strong>of</strong> DLDD processes <strong>and</strong><br />

their impacts; it also reflects the need to assess the costs <strong>of</strong> DLDD from the perspective <strong>of</strong> society as a<br />

whole—now <strong>and</strong> in the future. <strong>The</strong> choice <strong>of</strong> discount rate for the valuation <strong>of</strong> environmental goods is<br />

essentially an ethical issue, not one <strong>of</strong> economic calculation only.<br />

As stated earlier, the time preference <strong>of</strong> individuals, especially in developing countries, is<br />

<strong>of</strong>ten much higher than the value proposed here for the global analysis. For instance, for l<strong>and</strong><br />

degradation, a strong time preference can reflect constrained choices in l<strong>and</strong> management due to<br />

poverty, leading to l<strong>and</strong>-degrading rather than l<strong>and</strong>-conserving practices, or due to the l<strong>and</strong> user’s<br />

high level <strong>of</strong> risk aversion. Typically, in poor rural areas, l<strong>and</strong> degradation, poverty, <strong>and</strong> a high time<br />

preference are all interrelated, which can take the form <strong>of</strong> a vicious circle, as illustrated in Figure 1.4.<br />

As poverty increases, l<strong>and</strong> users form ever-higher preferences for the present over the future, thereby<br />

8

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!