14.01.2013 Views

The Economics of Desertification, Land Degradation, and Drought

The Economics of Desertification, Land Degradation, and Drought

The Economics of Desertification, Land Degradation, and Drought

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

enefits. Common indicators <strong>of</strong> economic returns are the net present values (NPVs) 34 <strong>and</strong> the internal<br />

rate <strong>of</strong> return (IRR), 35 which are used to compare alternative scenarios—in this case, adoption or no<br />

adoption <strong>of</strong> conservation practices.<br />

<strong>The</strong> analyst’s choice <strong>of</strong> the value for the discount rate <strong>and</strong> time horizon has a crucial impact<br />

on pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>and</strong>, thus, the results <strong>of</strong> CBA. Usually, discount rates differ depending on whether<br />

they refer to an individual or to the society as a whole. When CBA is applied to evaluate options from<br />

an individual’s perspective, discount rates are higher, as individuals are thought to have a higher time<br />

preference. This assumption is related to their attitudes toward risk <strong>and</strong> uncertainty, market<br />

distortions, <strong>and</strong> other institutional settings. From a society’s perspective, the use <strong>of</strong> low discount rates<br />

is justified with considerations on intergenerational equity <strong>and</strong> sustainability. Some authors use the<br />

current long-term rate <strong>of</strong> interest, provided by financial markets, as the appropriate discount rate<br />

(Crosson 1998). Studies have used discount rates ranging from 1 to 20 percent <strong>and</strong> time horizons from<br />

5 to 100 years. A useful review is provided in Clark (1996). It is <strong>of</strong>ten noted (see, for example,<br />

Barbier 1998) that CBA is a difficult implementation due to the required amount <strong>of</strong> information on<br />

costs <strong>and</strong> benefits. 36 When data are available, CBA can be specified to assess the pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> the<br />

adoption <strong>of</strong> conservation measures. Pr<strong>of</strong>its or returns to conservation measures are calculated as the<br />

difference between the value <strong>of</strong> the crop yields <strong>and</strong> the costs <strong>of</strong> production .37 Off-site <strong>and</strong> indirect<br />

costs also need to be subtracted from pr<strong>of</strong>it when the CBA is applied from society’s perspective. <strong>The</strong><br />

same procedure can be applied to nonconserving agricultural practices. <strong>The</strong> NPV <strong>of</strong> returns to<br />

conservation is therefore the difference between the discounted stream <strong>of</strong> pr<strong>of</strong>its with <strong>and</strong> without the<br />

implementation <strong>of</strong> conservation measures. This method usually estimates the returns to specific<br />

conservation measures, not to conservation per se (Lutz, Pagiola, <strong>and</strong> Reiche 1994).<br />

Numerous studies have applied CBA to analyze the pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> conservation practices in<br />

different areas <strong>of</strong> the world (see Appendix B). Whether conservation appeared to be pr<strong>of</strong>itable<br />

depended on the regions studied <strong>and</strong> the type <strong>of</strong> conservation measured (Lutz, Pagiola, <strong>and</strong> Reiche<br />

1994), the type <strong>of</strong> crops, the choice <strong>of</strong> discount rate (Shiferaw <strong>and</strong> Holden 2001), <strong>and</strong> the intensity <strong>of</strong><br />

a conservation measure (for example, hedgerow intensity) (Shively 1999). Nkonya et al. (2008b)<br />

found that sustainable l<strong>and</strong> management practices can be pr<strong>of</strong>itable from a private perspective as well<br />

as from society’s perspective.<br />

<strong>The</strong> decision to adopt conservation measures is based not only on economic reasons (such as<br />

costs <strong>and</strong> benefits) but also on a variety <strong>of</strong> other factors (Drake, Bergstrom, <strong>and</strong> Svedsater 1999). A<br />

number <strong>of</strong> studies that investigate the determinants <strong>of</strong> the adoption <strong>of</strong> soil <strong>and</strong> water conservation<br />

measures, other than primarily financial factors, are reviewed in a later section on adoption models.<br />

Economic Valuation <strong>of</strong> Nature <strong>and</strong> Its Services—A Review<br />

A full accounting <strong>of</strong> all the benefits deriving from the various ecosystem services in accordance to<br />

MA (2005b) is difficult to undertake. In this report, we focus on the economic benefits. This approach<br />

is based on a utilitarian philosophy, <strong>and</strong> it tends to underestimate the full costs. <strong>The</strong> utilitarian<br />

approach relies on the concept <strong>of</strong> utility as a measure <strong>of</strong> value: Alternative states are compared<br />

according to the utility they generate, irrespective <strong>of</strong> how this utility is derived. Environmental<br />

benefits are treated equally to any other benefit, assuming they can be traded <strong>of</strong>f. Usually, this means<br />

that a loss in environmental quality can be compensated for by an increase in another type <strong>of</strong><br />

34 Present value <strong>of</strong> cash inflows <strong>and</strong> cash outflows C; NPV is used to analyze the pr<strong>of</strong>itability <strong>of</strong> an investment. Index t<br />

represents the time dimension <strong>of</strong> the investment, <strong>and</strong> r is the discount rate.<br />

35 <strong>The</strong> IRR <strong>of</strong> an investment is the interest rate at which the NPV <strong>of</strong> the costs equals the NPV <strong>of</strong> the benefits <strong>of</strong> the<br />

investment. <strong>The</strong> higher a project’s internal rate <strong>of</strong> return, the more desirable it is to undertake the project.<br />

36 In its basic form, CBA does not consider the distribution <strong>of</strong> benefits <strong>and</strong> costs over individuals, <strong>and</strong> any increase in<br />

net benefits is desirable, regardless <strong>of</strong> to whom they occur (Barbier, Mark<strong>and</strong>ya, & Pearce 1998). Considerations about<br />

intergenerational equity are not part <strong>of</strong> CBA analysis, even when the costs <strong>and</strong> benefits <strong>of</strong> disadvantaged or poor population<br />

groups can be <strong>of</strong> greater importance than those <strong>of</strong> better-<strong>of</strong>f groups.<br />

37 Costs are usually related to additional labor <strong>and</strong> capital requirements for the conservation measure <strong>and</strong> the loss in<br />

productive area. Installing soil conservation measures leads to a reduction <strong>of</strong> the planted area, which is measured as a loss <strong>of</strong><br />

crop yield. Additional labor, sometimes capital, is needed to install <strong>and</strong> maintain conservation measures. Assumptions on<br />

labor inputs <strong>and</strong> wage rates may influence the outcome <strong>of</strong> CBA; therefore, it is important to obtain an accurate assessment <strong>of</strong><br />

the costs <strong>of</strong> labor <strong>and</strong> capital.<br />

67

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!