09.01.2015 Views

India: Effects of Tariffs and Nontariff Measures on U.S. ... - USITC

India: Effects of Tariffs and Nontariff Measures on U.S. ... - USITC

India: Effects of Tariffs and Nontariff Measures on U.S. ... - USITC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

Yet, 2007 was not a representative year for <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s wheat market. <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>n imports <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wheat<br />

fluctuate greatly from year to year <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> were unusually high in 2006 <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2007 by<br />

historical st<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>ards. <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s annual wheat imports in 2006 <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> 2007 amounted to<br />

approximately $1.3 billi<strong>on</strong> (5–6 milli<strong>on</strong> mt) in each year. By c<strong>on</strong>trast, in the 12-year<br />

period from 1997 to 2008, <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g> reported imports <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> less than $1 milli<strong>on</strong> (less than<br />

5,000 mt) during six years, including two years <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> zero imports, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> imports <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> $180–<br />

$280 milli<strong>on</strong> (700,000 mt to 2 milli<strong>on</strong> mt) in four years. An assumpti<strong>on</strong> that U.S. wheat<br />

sales would equal an amount equivalent to more than 20 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s 2007 wheat<br />

imports leads to unrealistically large displacement <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s domestic producti<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

wheat <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> similarly unrealistic effects <strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s other crops.<br />

Accordingly, we assumed that, in the absence <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>n NTMs, U.S. wheat exports to<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g> would represent the U.S. global share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> world wheat exports over a l<strong>on</strong>ger term,<br />

applied as a share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s typical imports <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> wheat. For the last 10 years in which <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

reported positive imports, the median imports amounted to approximately 1.04 milli<strong>on</strong> mt,<br />

or about 20.6 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s 2007 imports. The U.S. median share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> world wheat<br />

exports over the 10 years from 1999 to 2008 is 26.0 percent. Thus, a typical U.S. global<br />

market share in the l<strong>on</strong>g term <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s typical wheat imports amounts to approximately<br />

5.36 percent <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> <str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s 2007 imports. 18 This share was the basis for the estimati<strong>on</strong><br />

presented here.<br />

Simulati<strong>on</strong> <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> Ec<strong>on</strong>omic <str<strong>on</strong>g>Effects</str<strong>on</strong>g><br />

The NTM price gaps were aggregated to GTAP sectors, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the effects <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> their removal<br />

were simulated in the GTAP model. The estimated price gaps, before <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> after<br />

aggregati<strong>on</strong>, are presented in table 6.1. Because <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the large values for many <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the price<br />

gaps (100–1,000 percent), it is not computati<strong>on</strong>ally tractable to estimate their removal<br />

using a PE model simulati<strong>on</strong>. The aggregati<strong>on</strong> to GTAP sectors reflects the fact that, in<br />

some cases, estimated price gaps at the HS6 level apply to some products in the sector<br />

but not all, as reflected in table 6.1, which shows the difference between the average<br />

NTM price gaps for relevant products <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> for the GTAP sector. The price gaps were<br />

aggregated to the sector level using a method that holds the implied NTM rents for the<br />

aggregate equal to the sum <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> implied NTM rents at the HS6 level. 19 For wheat, the<br />

simulati<strong>on</strong> was performed in such a manner as to set the final share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> U.S. exports in<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>India</str<strong>on</strong>g>’s imports at 27 percent.<br />

A GTAP model simulati<strong>on</strong> baseline for the NTM estimates was prepared excluding the<br />

tariffs, <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the sector-specific price gaps were simulated as gaps between the c.i.f. value<br />

<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> the l<str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g>ed duty–paid value. Such price gaps were then removed. The results <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> this<br />

procedure are reported in table 6.2. These results include a sensitivity analysis with<br />

respect to the elasticities, similar to that performed for tariffs.<br />

18 206 * 0.260 = 0.0536, approximately.<br />

19 This method uses the relati<strong>on</strong><br />

(reference export unit value)*(1 + transport margin + NTM price gap) = (reference import unit value).<br />

Thus, implied NTM rents = (NTM price gap/(1 + transport margin + NTM price gap))*(value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c.i.f.<br />

imports).<br />

The usual method <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> trade weighting yields unrealistic results in this case because, for price gaps<br />

exceeding 100 percent, the implied tariff revenues are larger than the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> c.i.f. imports <str<strong>on</strong>g>and</str<strong>on</strong>g> not a realistic<br />

estimate <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> NTM rents, which must be a share <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> the value <str<strong>on</strong>g>of</str<strong>on</strong>g> imports.<br />

H-10

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!