01.02.2015 Views

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

<strong>Producer</strong> <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Index</strong> <strong>Manual</strong><br />

Let us say the price of a product m available in<br />

January (period t) is unavailable in March (period t<br />

+ 2). The price of product m can be predicted for<br />

March by inserting the characteristics of the old<br />

unavailable product m into the estimated regression<br />

equation for March, this process is repeated<br />

for successive months. The predicted price for the<br />

old product in March <strong>and</strong> the price comparison<br />

with January (period t) are given, respectively, by<br />

(7.25a)<br />

pˆ<br />

= exp ⎡β ˆ + β z ⎤<br />

⎣ ∑ ⎦<br />

,<br />

t+ 2 t+ 2 t+<br />

2 t<br />

m k k k,<br />

m<br />

t+<br />

2 t<br />

<strong>and</strong> pˆ m<br />

/ pm<br />

, that is, the old model’s price is adjusted.<br />

In the example in Table 7.2(a), pˆ<br />

ˆ<br />

3 4<br />

2,<br />

p<br />

2<br />

, etcetera<br />

<strong>and</strong> 3 4<br />

ˆp<br />

6<br />

, ˆp<br />

6<br />

, etcetera would be estimated<br />

1<br />

1<br />

<strong>and</strong> compared with p<br />

2<br />

<strong>and</strong> p<br />

6<br />

, respectively. The<br />

blanks for products 2 <strong>and</strong> 6 in Table 7.2(a) would<br />

be effectively filled in by the estimated price from<br />

the regression equation.<br />

7.140 An alternative procedure is to select for<br />

each unavailable m product a replacement product<br />

n. In this case, the price of n in period t + 2 is<br />

known, <strong>and</strong> a predicted price for n in period t is required.<br />

The predicted price for the new product<br />

<strong>and</strong> required price comparison are:<br />

(7.25b)<br />

t t t t 2<br />

pˆ<br />

n<br />

= exp ⎡<br />

⎣β 0<br />

+ ∑ βk z + ⎤<br />

k,<br />

m⎦,<br />

t+<br />

2 t<br />

<strong>and</strong> p / ˆ<br />

n<br />

pn<br />

, that is, the new model’s price is adjusted.<br />

In this case, the characteristics of product n<br />

are inserted into the right-h<strong>and</strong> side of an estimated<br />

regression for period t. The price comparisons of<br />

equation (7.25a) may be weighted by w t m<br />

, as would<br />

those of its replaced price comparison in equation<br />

(7.25b).<br />

7.141 A final alternative is to take the geometric<br />

mean of the formulations in equations (7.25a) <strong>and</strong><br />

(7.25b) on grounds analogous to those discussed in<br />

Chapter 15 <strong>and</strong> by Diewert (1997) for similar index<br />

number issues.<br />

7.142 Hedonic imputation: predicted vs. predicted—A<br />

further approach is the use of predicted<br />

values for the product in both periods, for example,<br />

t+<br />

2 t<br />

pˆ<br />

/ ˆ<br />

n<br />

pn, where n represents the product. Consider<br />

a misspecification problem in the hedonic equation.<br />

For example, there may be an interaction effect<br />

between a br<strong>and</strong> dummy <strong>and</strong> a characteristic,<br />

say between Dell <strong>and</strong> speed in the example in Table<br />

7.3. Having both characteristics may be worth<br />

more on price (from a semi-logarithmic form) than<br />

their separate individual components (for evidence<br />

of interaction effects see, Curry, Molgan <strong>and</strong> Silver,<br />

2000). The use of p / ˆ<br />

t+<br />

2 t<br />

n<br />

pn<br />

would be misleading<br />

since the actual price in the numerator would<br />

incorporate the 5 percent premium while the one<br />

predicted from a straightforward semi-logarithmic<br />

form would not. It is stressed that in adopting this<br />

approach, a recorded, actual price is being replaced<br />

by an imputation. Neither this nor the form of bias<br />

discussed above are desirable . Diewert (2002e)<br />

considers a similar problem <strong>and</strong> suggests an adjustment<br />

to bring the actual price back in line with<br />

the hedonic one.<br />

7.143 The comparisons using predicted values in<br />

both periods are given as<br />

pˆ<br />

pˆ<br />

t+<br />

2<br />

n<br />

t+<br />

2<br />

m<br />

/ pˆ<br />

for the new product,<br />

t<br />

n<br />

/ pˆ<br />

t<br />

m<br />

for the disappearing or old product, or<br />

t+ (7.26) ( 2 t t+<br />

ˆ / ˆ )( ˆ 2 t<br />

⎡ p p p / pˆ<br />

) ⎤<br />

12<br />

⎣ n n m m ⎦<br />

as a (geometric) mean of the two.<br />

7.144 Hedonic adjustments using coefficients—<br />

In this approach, a replacement product is used <strong>and</strong><br />

any differences between the characteristics of the<br />

replacement n in t + 2 <strong>and</strong> m in period t are ascertained.<br />

A predicted price for n in period t, that is,<br />

ˆ t<br />

n<br />

t 2<br />

p is compared with the actual price, p +<br />

n<br />

. However,<br />

unlike the formulation in equation (7.25b) for<br />

example, p ˆ t<br />

n<br />

, may be estimated by applying the<br />

subset of the k characteristics that distinguished m<br />

from n, to their respective implicit prices in period<br />

t estimated from the hedonic regression, <strong>and</strong> ad-<br />

t<br />

justing the price of p<br />

m<br />

. For example, if the nearest<br />

replacement for product 2 was product 3, then the<br />

characteristics that differentiated product 3 from<br />

product 2 are identified <strong>and</strong> the price in the base<br />

1<br />

period p3<br />

is estimated by adjusting p 1 2<br />

using the<br />

appropriate coefficients from the hedonic regression<br />

in that month. For example, for washing machines,<br />

if product 2 had an 800 revolutions pre<br />

minute (rpm) spin speed <strong>and</strong> product 3 had an<br />

1,100 rpm spin speed, other things being equal, the<br />

shadow price of the 300 rpm differential would be<br />

estimated from the hedonic regression, <strong>and</strong> p<br />

1 2<br />

176

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!