01.02.2015 Views

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

You also want an ePaper? Increase the reach of your titles

YUMPU automatically turns print PDFs into web optimized ePapers that Google loves.

<strong>Producer</strong> <strong>Price</strong> <strong>Index</strong> <strong>Manual</strong><br />

in response to changes in their relative prices. In the<br />

absence of information about quantities or revenues<br />

within an elementary aggregate, an ideal index can<br />

be estimated only when certain special conditions<br />

are assumed to prevail.<br />

9.32 There are two special cases of some interest.<br />

The first case is when producers continue to<br />

produce the same relative quantities whatever the<br />

relative prices. <strong>Producer</strong>s prefer not to make any<br />

substitutions in response to changes in relative<br />

prices. The cross elasticities of supply are zero. The<br />

technology by which inputs are translated into outputs<br />

in economic theory is described by a production<br />

function, <strong>and</strong> a production function with such a<br />

restrictive reaction to relative price changes is described<br />

in the economics literature as Leontief.<br />

With such a production function, a Laspeyres index<br />

would provide an exact measure of the ideal economic<br />

index. In this case, the Carli index calculated<br />

for a r<strong>and</strong>om sample of products would provide an<br />

estimate of the ideal economic index that the products<br />

are selected with probabilities proportional to<br />

the population revenue shares. 1<br />

9.33 The second case occurs when producers<br />

are assumed to vary the quantities they produce in<br />

inverse proportion to the changes in relative prices.<br />

The cross-elasticities of supply between the different<br />

products they produce are all unity, the revenue<br />

shares remaining the same in both periods. Such an<br />

underlying production function is described as<br />

Cobb-Douglas. With this production function, the<br />

Geometric Laspeyres 2 index would provide an exact<br />

measure of the ideal index. In this case, the Jevons<br />

index calculated for a r<strong>and</strong>om sample of products<br />

would provide an unbiased estimate of the<br />

ideal economic index provided that the products are<br />

selected with probabilities proportional to the population<br />

expenditure shares.<br />

1 It might appear that if the products were selected with<br />

probabilities proportional to the population quantity shares,<br />

the sample Dutot would provide an estimate of the population<br />

Laspeyres. However, if the basket for the Laspeyres index<br />

contains different kinds of products whose quantities are<br />

not additive, the quantity shares, <strong>and</strong> hence the probabilities,<br />

are undefined.<br />

2 The Geometric Laspeyres is a weighted geometric average<br />

of the price relatives, using the revenue shares in the<br />

earlier period as weights. (The revenue shares in the second<br />

period would be the same in the particular case under consideration).<br />

9.34 From the economic approach, the choice<br />

between the sample Jevons index <strong>and</strong> the sample<br />

Carli index rests on which is likely to approximate<br />

more closely the underlying ideal economic index—in<br />

other words, whether the (unknown) crosselasticities<br />

are likely to be closer to unity or zero,<br />

on average. In practice, the cross-elasticities could<br />

take on any value ranging up to +∞ for an elementary<br />

aggregate consisting of a set of strictly homogeneous<br />

products—that is, perfect substitutes 3 . It<br />

may be conjectured that for dem<strong>and</strong>-led industries<br />

where producers produce less of a commodity<br />

whose relative price has increased to meet the reduced<br />

quantity dem<strong>and</strong>ed, the average cross elasticity<br />

is likely to be closer to unity. Thus the Jevons<br />

index is likely to provide a closer approximation to<br />

the ideal economic index than the Carli index. In<br />

this case, the Carli index must be viewed as having<br />

an upward bias. However, there are some establishments<br />

in industries, including utilities, in which<br />

supply is relatively unresponsive to dem<strong>and</strong><br />

changes, <strong>and</strong> the Carli index would be more appropriate,<br />

given that sampling is with probability proportional<br />

to base-period revenue shares. And, yet<br />

again, there would be establishments in industries<br />

in which quantities produced increase as prices increase<br />

<strong>and</strong>, with probability sampling proportional<br />

to base-period revenues, neither the Carli nor the<br />

Jevons index would be appropriate from the economic<br />

approach.<br />

9.35 The insight provided by the economic approach<br />

is that the Jevons <strong>and</strong> Carli indices can be<br />

justified from the economic approach depending on<br />

whether a significant amount substitution is more<br />

likely than no substitution, especially as elementary<br />

aggregates should be deliberately constructed to<br />

group together similar products that are close substitutes<br />

for each other.<br />

9.36 The Jevons index does not imply, or assume,<br />

that revenue shares remain constant. Obviously,<br />

the Jevons can be calculated whatever<br />

changes do or do not occur in the revenue shares in<br />

practice. What the economic approach shows is that<br />

if the revenue shares remain constant (or roughly<br />

constant), then the Jevons index can be expected to<br />

provide a good estimate of the underlying ideal<br />

3 It should be noted that in the limit when the products<br />

really are homogeneous, there is no index number problem,<br />

<strong>and</strong> the price “index” is given by the ratio of the unit values<br />

in the two periods, as explained below.<br />

220

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!