01.02.2015 Views

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

Producer Price Index Manual: Theory and Practice ... - METAC

SHOW MORE
SHOW LESS

Create successful ePaper yourself

Turn your PDF publications into a flip-book with our unique Google optimized e-Paper software.

22. Treatment of Seasonal Products<br />

proximations to them can be constructed. 11 For<br />

each month m = 1, 2,...,12, let S(m) denote the set<br />

of products that are available for purchase in each<br />

year t = 0, 1,...,T. For t = 0, 1,...,T <strong>and</strong> m = 1,<br />

2,...,12, let p t,m n <strong>and</strong> q t,m n denote the price <strong>and</strong><br />

quantity of product n that is available in month m<br />

of year t for n belongs to S(m). Let p t,m <strong>and</strong> q t,m<br />

denote the month m <strong>and</strong> year t price <strong>and</strong> quantity<br />

vectors, respectively. Then the year-over-year<br />

monthly Laspeyres, Paasche, <strong>and</strong> Fisher indices<br />

going from month m of year t to month m of year<br />

t+1 can be defined as follows:<br />

tm , t+<br />

1, m tm ,<br />

(22.1) PL<br />

( p , p , q )<br />

m = 1, 2,...12;<br />

t, m t+ 1, m t+<br />

1, m<br />

(22.2) P ( p , p , q )<br />

m = 1,,2,...12;<br />

=<br />

∑<br />

n∈<br />

S( m)<br />

=<br />

∑<br />

n∈<br />

S( m)<br />

∑<br />

p<br />

q<br />

t+<br />

1, m t,<br />

m<br />

n n<br />

p<br />

n∈<br />

S( m)<br />

∑<br />

n∈<br />

S( m)<br />

q<br />

tm , tm ,<br />

n n<br />

p<br />

q<br />

;<br />

t+ 1, m t+<br />

1, m<br />

n n<br />

p<br />

q<br />

tm , t+<br />

1, m<br />

n n<br />

tm , t+ 1, m tm , t+<br />

1, m<br />

(22.3) PF<br />

( p , p , q , q )<br />

t, m t+ 1, m t, m t, m t+ 1, m t+<br />

1, m<br />

PL( p , p , q ) P ( p , p , q )<br />

≡ ;<br />

m = 1, 2,...,12.<br />

22.20 The above formulas can be rewritten in<br />

price relative <strong>and</strong> monthly revenue share form as<br />

follows:<br />

tm , t+ 1, m tm , tm , t+<br />

1, m tm ,<br />

(22.4) PL( p , p , s ) sn ( pn pn<br />

)<br />

m = 1, 2,...12;<br />

t, m t+ 1, m t+<br />

1, m<br />

(22.5) P ( p , p , s )<br />

m = 1, 2,...12;<br />

= ∑ ;<br />

n∈S( m)<br />

−1<br />

∑<br />

t 1, m t 1, m t,<br />

m<br />

−1⎤<br />

+ +<br />

sn ( pn pn<br />

) ;<br />

n∈S( m)<br />

⎡<br />

= ⎢ ⎥<br />

⎢⎣<br />

⎥⎦<br />

11 Diewert (1996b, pp. 17–19; 1999a, p. 50) noted various<br />

separability restrictions on purchaser preferences that<br />

would justify these year-over-year monthly indices from<br />

the viewpoint of the economic approach to index number<br />

theory.<br />

;<br />

tm , t+ 1, m tm , t+<br />

1, m<br />

(22.6) PF<br />

( p , p , s , s )<br />

tm , t+<br />

1, m tm ,<br />

t, m t+ 1, m t+<br />

1, m<br />

≡ PL<br />

( p , p , s ) P ( p , p , s )<br />

m = 1, 2,...,12<br />

;<br />

−1<br />

−1<br />

⎡<br />

⎤<br />

tm , t+ 1, m tm , tm , t+<br />

1, m tm ,<br />

= ∑ sn ( pn pn ) ⎢ ∑ sn ( pn pn<br />

) ⎥<br />

n∈S( m)<br />

⎢⎣n∈S ( m)<br />

⎥⎦<br />

where the monthly revenue share for product<br />

n∈S(m) for month m in year t is defined as:<br />

(22.7)<br />

s<br />

p q<br />

= ; ; m = 1, 2,...,12 ;<br />

∑<br />

tm , tm ,<br />

tm ,<br />

n n<br />

n tm , tm ,<br />

pi<br />

qi<br />

i∈S( m)<br />

n∈S(m) ; t = 0,1,...,T;<br />

<strong>and</strong> s t,m denotes the vector of month m expenditure<br />

shares in year t, [s n t,m ] for n∈S(m).<br />

22.21 Current period revenue shares s n t,m are not<br />

likely to be available. As a consequence, it will be<br />

necessary to approximate these shares using the<br />

corresponding revenue shares from a base year 0.<br />

22.22 Use the base period monthly revenue<br />

share vectors s 0,m in place of the vector of month m<br />

<strong>and</strong> year t expenditure shares s t,m in equation (22.4)<br />

<strong>and</strong> use the base period monthly expenditure share<br />

vectors s 0,m in place of the vector of month m <strong>and</strong><br />

year t + 1 revenue shares s t+1,m in equation (22.5).<br />

Similarly, replace the share vectors s t,m <strong>and</strong> s t+1,m in<br />

equation (22.6) with the base period expenditure<br />

share vector for month m, s 0,m . The resulting approximate<br />

year-over-year monthly Laspeyres,<br />

Paasche, <strong>and</strong> Fisher indices are defined by equations<br />

(22.8)–(22.10) below: 12<br />

12 If the monthly revenue shares for the base year, s n 0,m ,<br />

are all equal, then the approximate Fisher index defined by<br />

(22.10) reduces to Fisher’s (1922, p. 472) formula 101.<br />

Fisher (1922, p. 211) observed that this index was empirically<br />

very close to the unweighted geometric mean of the<br />

price relatives, while Dalén (1992a, p. 143) <strong>and</strong> Diewert<br />

(1995a, p. 29) showed analytically that these two indices<br />

approximated each other to the second order. The equally<br />

weighted version of equation (22.10) was recommended as<br />

an elementary index by Carruthers, Sellwood, <strong>and</strong> Ward<br />

(1980, p. 25) <strong>and</strong> Dalén (1992a p. 140).<br />

559

Hooray! Your file is uploaded and ready to be published.

Saved successfully!

Ooh no, something went wrong!